A-226-89
Canadian National Railway Company (Respond-
ent) (Plaintiff)
v.
Norsk Pacific Steamship Company Limited,
Norsk Pacific Marine Services Ltd., Fletcher
Challenge Ltd., the tug Jervis Crown, Francis
MacDonnell (Appellants) (Defendants)
and
Crown Forest Industries Ltd., the barge Crown
Forest No. 4, Rivtow Straits Ltd. and R.V.C.
Holdings Ltd. operating under the firm name and
style of Westminster Tug Boats and the said
Westminster Tug Boats, the tug Westminster Chi-
nook and Barry Smith (Defendants)
and
Her Majesty the Queen (Respondent) (Third
Party)
INDEXED AS: CANADIAN NATIONAL RAILWAY CO. V. NORSK
PACIFIC STEAMSHIP CO. (CA.)
Court of Appeal, Heald, Stone and MacGuigan
JJ.A.—Ottawa, November 7, 8 and 9, 1989; Janu-
ary 5, 1990.
Torts — Negligence — Pure economic loss — Collision
between log barge in tow of tug and railway bridge property of
federal Crown causing bridge closure and rerouting of railway
traffic — Trial Judge did not err in finding owners and
managers of tug liable in negligence for pure economic loss in
absence of damage to CNR's property — Requirements of
reasonable foreseeability and sufficient degree of proximity
between tortfeasor and claimant met.
Maritime law — Torts — Collision between log barge in tow
of tug and railway bridge — Trial Judge did not err in holding
owners and managers of tug liable in negligence for pure
economic loss suffered by railway due to bridge closure
Reasonable foreseeability and sufficient degree of proximity
tests met.
Railways — Log barge in tow of tug colliding with railway
bridge owned by federal Crown — Temporary bridge closure
requiring CNR to reroute trains — CNR awarded damages for
pure economic loss — Trial Judge correct in holding owners
and managers of tug liable in negligence for pure economic
loss in absence of physical damage to CNR's property.
This is an appeal by the owner and master of the tug Jervis
Crown from a judgment awarding the Canadian National
Railway Company ("CNR") damages in tort for economic loss
arising from a collision between a log barge in tow of the tug
and a bridge owned by Public Works Canada ("PWC") and
used by CNR to cross the Fraser River at New Westminster,
British Columbia.
Negligence as to the collision was admitted. There being no
claims for loss of freight revenue, but solely for the additional
costs of operation, CNR and two other railways were awarded
the costs incurred in rerouting their trains over another bridge.
It was agreed before trial that the claims of the other two
railways would stand or fall on the result of the CNR's claim.
It is therefore only the latter's claim which is directly in issue
on this appeal.
The question is whether the Trial Judge was correct in
holding that the appellants could be held liable in negligence
for pure economic loss in the absence of any physical damage to
CNR's property.
Held, the appeal should be dismissed.
Per Stone J.A.: A loss to be recoverable must not only be
foreseeable; there must also be a sufficient proximity or "neigh-
bourhood" between a wrongdoer and a plaintiff such as to give
rise to a duty of care owed by the former to the latter.
The following elements were found important by the Trial
Judge in determining liability for pure economic loss: knowl
edge of the claimant as a specific individual or identity likely to
suffer the damage as opposed to knowledge of a general class of
people; foreseeability of the precise nature of the loss; and
sufficient degree of proximity between the act committed by
the tortfeasor and the injury complained of "that an ordinary
right thinking person would feel that the tortfeasor is morally
bound to compensate the victim". Taken collectively, if not
perhaps individually, those elements demonstrate that sufficient
proximity giving rise to a duty of care owed by the appellants to
CNR existed. In the exceptional circumstances of the case,
there was no reason in policy for negativing this duty of care or
for denying recovery of the loss.
Per MacGuigan J.A. (Heald J.A. concurring): It can be
concluded from the Supreme Court of Canada decisions in
Rivtow Marine, Agnew-Surpass, Haig and Baird that there is
no absolute rule in Canada preventing recovery for pure eco
nomic loss even where there is no physical damage to the
plaintiffs property.
The case law shows that for liability to arise in the case of
pure economic loss, courts require, in addition to the general
principle of reasonable foresight, that there be a sufficient
proximity between the plaintiff and the defendant. Resolution
of liability for economic loss is not a policy decision. One
should rather look to principle and think of the judgment
required for liability as a perception of sufficient proximity.
The best statement of the proximity principle is that formu
lated by Deane J. of the High Court of Australia in Sutherland
Shire Council v. Heyman. His Lordship said that proximity
embraced various forms: "physical proximity (in the sense of
space and time) between the person or property of the plaintiff
and that of the defendant; circumstantial proximity such as an
overriding relationship of employer and employee or of a
professional man and his client; causal proximity in the sense of
closeness or directness of the causal connection between the
particular act and the injury sustained; assumed proximity
which reflects an assumption by one party of a responsibility to
take care to prevent injury, or reliance by one party upon such
care being taken by the other in circumstances where the other
party knew or ought to have known of that reliance". It was
also said that "the requirement of a relationship of proximity
serves as a touchstone and control of the categories of cases in
which the common law will adjudge that a duty of care is
owed".
The actual knowledge of the appellants found by the Trial
Judge (knowledge of the CNR as a party likely to suffer
damage and knowledge of the precise nature of the loss) was
not necessary for liability; all that was required in that regard
was reasonable foreseeability. The principle of sufficient prox
imity was realized particularly by the third ground advanced by
the Trial Judge to the effect that the property of the CNR (the
tracks on both sides of the river) was not only in close proximi
ty to the bridge but it could not properly be enjoyed without the
essential link of the bridge. In effect, the Trial Judge found that
the CNR was so closely assimilated to the position of PWC
that it was very much within the reasonable ambit of risk of the
appellants at the time of the accident. That constituted both
"physical and circumstantial closeness".
CASES JUDICIALLY CONSIDERED
CONSIDERED:
Attorney-General for Ontario v. Fatehi et al. (1981), 34
O.R. (2d) 129; 127 D.L.R. (3d) 603; 18 C.C.L.T. 97; 13
M.V.R. 180 (C.A.); revd on other grounds [1984] 2
S.C.R. 536; (1984), 15 D.L.R. (4th) 132; 31 C.C.L.T.
1; 31 M.V.R. 301; 56 N.R. 62; 60 A.C. 270; D. & F.
Estates Ltd. v. Church Comrs. for England, [1989] 1
A.C. 177 (H.L.); Anns v. Merton London Borough
Council, [1978] A.C. 728 (H.L.); Donoghue v. Steven-
son, [1932] A.C. 562 (H.L.); Dorset Yacht Co. Ltd. v.
Home Office, [1970] A.C. 1004 (H.L.); Hedley Byrne &
Co. Ltd. v. Heller & Partners Ltd., [1964] A.C. 465
(H.L.); Caltex Oil (Australia) Pty. Ltd. v. The Dredge
"Willemstad" (1976), 136 C.L.R. 529; 11 A.L.R. 227
(H.C.); Junior Books Ltd. v. Veitchi Co. Ltd., [1983]
A.C. 520; [1982] 3 All ER 201 (H.L.); Candlewood
Navigation Corpn. Ltd. v. Mitsui O.S.K. Lines Ltd.
("The Mineral Transporter"], [1986] A.C. 1; [1985] 2
All ER 935 (P.C.); Leigh and Sillavan Ltd. v. Aliakmon
Shipping Co. Ltd., [1986] A.C. 785; [1986] 2 All ER 145
(H.L.); Rivtow Marine Ltd. v. Washington Iron Works et
al., [1974] S.C.R. 1189; (1973), 40 D.L.R. (3d) 530;
[1973] 6 W.W.R. 692; Kamloops (City of) v. Nielsen et
al., [1984] 2 S.C.R. 2; (1984), 10 D.L.R. (4th) 641;
[1984] 5 W.W.R. 1; 29 C.C.L.T. 97; Agnew-Surpass
Shoe Stores Ltd. v. Cummer-Yonge Investments Ltd.,
[1976] 2 S.C.R. 221; (1975), 55 D.L.R. (3d) 676; [1975]
I.L.R. 1-675; 4 N.R. 547; Haig v. Bamford et al., [1977]
1 S.C.R. 466; (1976), 72 D.L.R. (3d) 68; [1976] 3
W.W.R. 331; 27 C.P.R. (2d) 149; 9 N.R. 43; B.D.C. Ltd.
v. Hofstrand Farms Ltd., [1986] 1 S.C.R. 228; (1986),
26 D.L.R. (4th) 1; [1986] 3 W.W.R. 216; 1 B.C.L.R.
(2d) 324; 36 C.C.L.T. 87; 65 N.R. 261; Central Trust
Co. v. Rafuse, [1986] 2 S.C.R. 147; (1986), 75 N.S.R.
(2d) 109; 31 D.L.R. (4th) 481; 186 A.P.R. 109; 34
B.L.R. 187; 37 C.C.L.T. 117; 42 R.P.C. 161; Baird v.
The Queen in right of Canada, [1984] 2 F.C. 160;
(1983), 148 D.L.R. (3d) 1; 48 N.R. 276 (C.A.); Gypsum
Carrier Inc. v. The Queen, [1978] 1 F.C. 147; (1977), 78
D.L.R. (3d) 175 (T.D.): Bethlehem Steel Corporation v.
St. Lawrence Seaway Authority, [1978] 1 F.C. 464;
(1977), 79 D.L.R. (3d) 522 (T.D.); Interocean Shipping
Company v. The Ship Atlantic Splendour, [1984] 1 F.C.
931; (1983), 26 C.C.L.T. 189 (T.D.); Nicholls v. Town
ship of Richmond et al. (1983), 145 D.L.R. (3d) 362;
[1983] 4 W.W.R. 169; 43 B.C.L.R. 162; 1 C.C.E.L. 188;
24 C.C.L.T. 253; 33 C.P.C. 310 (C.A.); Maughan and
Maughan v. International Harvester Company of
Canada Limited (1980), 38 N.S.R. (2d) 101; 112 D.L.R.
(3d) 243 (C.A.); Yumerovski et al. v. Dani (1977), 18
O.R. (2d) 704; 83 D.L.R. (3d) 558; 4 C.C.L.T. 233 (Co.
Ct.); affd (1979), 120 D.L.R. (3d) 768 (Ont. C.A.);
Sutherland Shire Council v. Heyman (1985), 60 ALR 1
(H.C.); Simpson v. Thomson (1877), 3 App. Cas. 279
(H.L.); Hill v. Chief Constable of West Yorkshire,
[1989] A.C. 53 (H.L.); Yeun Kun Yeu v. Attorney-Gen
eral of Hong Kong, [1988] A.C. 175 (P.C.).
REFERRED TO:
Cattle v. Stockton Waterworks Company (1875), L.R. 10
Q.B. 453; Ultramares Corporation v. Touche, 255 N.Y.
170; 174 N.E. 441 (Ct. App. 1931); Morrison Steamship
Co., Ld. v. Greystoke Castle (Cargo Owners), [1947]
A.C. 265 (H.L.); East River S.S. Corp. v. Transamerica
Delaval, Inc., 106 S. Ct. 2295 (1986); Reid v. Rush &
Tompkins Group plc, [1989] 3 All ER 228 (C.A.);
Nunes Diamonds (J.) Ltd. v. Dominion Electric Protec
tion Co., [1972] S.C.R. 769; (1972), 26 D.L.R. (3d) 699;
University of Regina v. Pettick et al. (1986), 51 Sask. R.
270; 38 C.C.L.T. 230; 23 C.L.R. 204 (Q.B.); Dominion
Tape of Canada Ltd. v. L. R. McDonald & Sons Ltd. et
al., [1971] 3 O.R. 627; (1971), 21 D.L.R. (3d) 299 (Co.
Ct.); Smith et al. v. Melancon, [1976] 4 W.W.R. 9
(B.C.S.C.); MacMillan Bloedel Ltd. v. Foundation Com
pany of Canada Ltd. (1977), 75 D.L.R. (3d) 294; [1977]
2 W.W.R. 717; 1 C.C.L.T. 358 (B.C.S.C.); Trappa
Holdings Ltd. v. District of Surrey et al. (1978), 95
D.L.R. (3d) 107; [1978] 6 W.W.R. 545 (B.C.S.C.); Gold
v. The DeHavilland Aircraft of Can. Ltd., [1983] 6
W.W.R. 229; (1983), 25 C.C.L.T. 180 (B.C.S.C.); Spar
tan Steel & Alloys Ltd. v. Martin & Co. (Contractors)
Ltd., [1973] Q.B. 27 (C.A.); S.C.M. (United Kingdom)
Ltd. v. W. J. Whittall and Son Ltd., [1971] 1 Q.B. 337
(C.A.); Ross v. Caunters, [1980] Ch. 297; Lumley v. Gye
(1853), 2 El. & Bl. 216 (Q.B.).
AUTHORS CITED
Atiyah, P. S. "Negligence and Economic Loss"
(1967), 83 L.Q. Rev. 248.
Blom, Joost. "Economic Loss: Curbs on the Way
Ahead?" (1987), 12 Can. Bus. L.J. 275.
Burns, Peter J. "Recent Developments in Negligence
Law" in Negligence Law in the 1990's. Vancouver:
Continuing Legal Education Society of British
Columbia, 1985.
Cane, Peter. "Economic Loss in Tort: Is the Pendulum
Out of Control?" (1989), 52 Mod. L. Rev. 200.
Feldthusen, Bruce. Economic Negligence, 2nd ed.
Toronto: Carswell, 1989.
Feldthusen, Bruce. "Economic Loss: Where Are We
Going After Junior Books?" (1987), 12 Can. Bus. L.J.
241.
Feldthusen, Bruce. "Pure Economic Loss Consequent
Upon Physical Damage to a Third Party" (1977), 16
U.W.O.L. Rev. 1.
Fleming, John G. The Law of Torts, 7th ed. Sydney: Law
Book Co. Ltd., 1987.
Jones, Michael A. "Economic Loss—A Return to Prag
matism" (1986), 102 L.Q. Rev. 13.
Jutras, Daniel. "Civil Law and Pure Economic Loss:
What Are We Missing?" (1987), 12 Can. Bus. L.J.
295.
Linden, Allen M. Canadian Tort Law, 4th ed. Toronto:
Butterworths, 1988.
Markesinis, B. S. "An Expanding Tort Law—The Price
of a Rigid Contract Law" (1987), 103 L.Q. Rev. 354.
Smilie, J. A. "Negligence and Economic Loss"
(1982), 32 U.T.L.J. 231.
COUNSEL:
P. D. Lowry and J. W. Perrett for appellants
(defendants).
David F. McEwen for respondent (plaintiff)
Canadian National Railway Company.
SOLICITORS:
Campney & Murphy, Vancouver, for appel
lants (defendants).
McEwen, Schmitt & Co., Vancouver, for
respondent (plaintiff) Canadian National
Railway Company.
The following are the reasons for judgment
rendered in English by
STONE J.A.: I respectfully agree with Mr. Jus
tice MacGuigan that in the circumstances of this
case a duty of care was owed by the appellants
(defendants) to the respondent (plaintiff) and,
accordingly, that the former are liable to make
good the pure economic loss sustained by the
latter. I am also in general agreement with the
reasons proposed by him, but wish to add these
reasons for so concluding.
I accept from the outset that the issue whether
and in what circumstances the law should permit
recovery for pure economic loss is a "vexatious"'
one. Courts of highest authority have shown vary
ing degrees of reluctance to permit inroads on the
exclusionary rule laid down in Cattle v. Stockton
Waterworks Company (1875), L.R. 10 Q.B. 453
and upheld by the House of Lords in Simpson v.
Thomson (1877), 3 App. Cas. 279. Indeed, Mr.
Lowry submits that the rule has stood now for
more than a century and remains good law both in
the United Kingdom as in Canada, and also that
such judicial inroads as may have occurred have
been carefully circumscribed.
I begin with a brief review of the foundation
cases. The plaintiff in Cattle contracted with
Knight, the owner of lands adjoining both sides of
a road, to make a tunnel under the road so as to
connect the lands on both sides, the soil of the road
itself being declared by statute to be in the owners
of the adjoining land. The work was delayed and
the plaintiff was put to expense when water leak
ing from the defendant's watermain higher up on
the road interfered with the performance of the
work. The claim was one for pure economic (or
financial) loss flowing from this interference with
the plaintiff's right to enjoy a higher return of
profit from the contract. In rejecting the claim,
Blackburn J. asked (at page 457) whether the
plaintiff Cattle could "sue in his own name for the
loss which he has in fact sustained, in consequence
of the damage, which the defendants have done to
the property of Knight, causing him, Cattle, to lose
' Per Wilson J., in Kamloops (City of) v. Nielsen et al.,
[1984] 2 S.C.R. 2, at p. 25.
money under his contract?", and he answered the
question in the negative. His reasons for so doing
are stated succinctly, at pages 457-458:
In the present case the objection is technical and against the
merits, and we should be glad to avoid giving it effect. But if we
did so, we should establish an authority for saying that, in such
a case as that of Fletcher v. Rylands [Law Rep. 1 Ex. 265; Law
Rep. 3 H.L. 330) the defendant would be liable, not only to an
action by the owner of the drowned mine, and by such of his
workmen as had their tools or clothes destroyed, but also to an
action by every workman and person employed in the mine,
who in consequence of its stoppage made less wages than he
would otherwise have done. And many similar cases to which
this would apply might be suggested. It may be said that it is
just that all such persons should have compensation for such a
loss, and that, if the law does not give them redress, it is
imperfect. Perhaps it may be so. But, as was pointed out by
Coleridge, J., in Lumley v. Gye (2 E. & B. at p. 252; 22 L. J.
(Q.B.) at p. 479), Courts of justice should not "allow them
selves, in the pursuit of perfectly complete remedies for all
wrongful acts, to transgress the bounds, which our law, in a
wise consciousness as I conceive of its limited powers, has
imposed on itself, of redressing only the proximate and direct
consequences of wrongful acts." In this we quite agree. No
authority in favour of the plaintiffs right to sue was cited, and,
as far as our knowledge goes, there was none that could have
been cited.
• • •
In the present case there is ... at most ... a neglect of duty,
which occasioned injury to the property of Knight, but which
did not injure any property of the plaintiff. The plaintiffs claim
is to recover the damage which he has sustained by his contract
with Knight becoming less profitable, or, it may be, a losing
contract, in consequence of this injury to Knight's property. We
think this does not give him any right of action.
Two years later, the reasons underlying the rule
were further articulated by Lord Penzance in
Simpson, supra, at page 289:
But in the argument at your Lordships' Bar the learned
Counsel for the Respondents took their stand upon a much
broader ground. They contended that the underwriters, by
virtue of the policy which they entered into in respect of this
ship, had an interest of their own in her welfare and protection,
inasmuch as any injury or loss sustained by her would indirect
ly fall upon them as a consequence of their contract; and that
this interest was such as would support an action by them in
their own names and behalf against a wrong-doer. This proposi-
tion virtually affirms a principle which I think your Lordships
will do well to consider with some care, as it will be found to
have a much wider application and signification than any which
may be involved in the incidents of a contract of insurance. The
principle involved seems to me to be this—that where damage
is done by a wrongdoer to a chattel not only the owner of that
chattel, but all those who by contract with the owner have
bound themselves to obligations which are rendered more oner
ous, or have secured to themselves advantages which are ren
dered less beneficial by the damage done to the chattel, have a
right of action against the wrongdoer although they have no
immediate or reversionary property in the chattel, and no
possessory right by reason of any contract attaching to the
chattel itself, such as by lien or hypothecation.
The appellants (defendants) contend that the
exclusionary rule has been recognized in Canada
by the highest authority, and cite by way of exam
ple references to Cattle in Rivtow Marine Ltd. v.
Washington Iron Works et al., [1974] S.C.R.
1189; and in Kamloops (City of) v. Nielsen et al.,
[1984] 2 S.C.R. 2. Further, in Attorney-General
for Ontario v. Fatehi et al. (1981), 34 O.R. (2d)
129 (C.A.), (reversed on other grounds [1984] 2
S.C.R. 536), Wilson J.A. (as she then was), after
canvassing the authorities including the view
expressed by Pigeon J. in Agnew-Surpass Shoe
Stores Ltd. v. Cummer-Yonge Investments Ltd.,
[1976] 2 S.C.R. 221, at page 252 that it had been
settled in Rivtow "that recovery for economic loss
caused by negligence is allowable without any
recovery for property damage", observed at
page 139:
Despite this, the exclusionary rule dies hard. In two recent
cases, Bethlehem Steel Corp. v. St. Lawrence Seaway Author
ity et al., [1978] 1 F.C. 464, 79 D.L.R. (3d) 522, and Hal-
Canadian Investments Ltd. v. North Shore Plumbing & Heat
ing Co. Ltd. et al., [1978] 4 W.W.R. 289 (B.C.S.C.), the right
to recovery for pure economic loss was limited to cases where
there had also been physical damage to person or property or
where such physical damage was threatened.
And, at page 140, she added:
I have concluded from a review of the leading English and
Canadian authorities that, while Canadian courts have made
greater inroads into the exclusionary rule than the English
courts, there has been no dramatic movement away from it
despite the observation of Mr. Justice Pigeon in the Agnew-
Surpass case, supra. I say this because the majority in Rivtow,
supra, found it necessary to base recovery on the existence of
an independent tort, breach of the duty to warn arising from
the special relationship between the parties, and Laskin J.
required a threat of physical damage to person or property.
None of the Court seems to have been prepared to go as far as
Lord Justice Edmund Davies in his dissenting judgment in the
Spartan Steel case, supra, and permit recovery of the economic
loss as a direct and reasonably foreseeable consequence of the
defect in the design or manufacture of the crane. In cases
where there is no independent tort and no threat of physical
damage the exclusionary rule would seem to be still very much
alive in Canada.
The appellants (defendants) lay much stress on
three recent decisions of the House of Lords and
the Privy Council as reaffirming the exclusionary
rule in English common law, in none of which was
a claim for pure economic loss allowed. The first,
Candlewood Navigation Corpn. Ltd. v. Mitsui
O.S.K. Lines Ltd. ["The Mineral Transporter"],
[1986] A.C. 1 (P.C.), involved a claim by a bare-
boat charterer for the cost of repairing a ship
damaged in a collision with another ship, as well as
a claim by a time charterer (also the owner of the
ship) for loss of charter hire and lost profits during
the time the ship was laid up. In Leigh and
Sillavan Ltd. v. Aliakmon Shipping Co. Ltd.,
[1986] A.C. 785 (H.L.), the plaintiff, a c & f
buyer of goods carried in a ship, claimed against
the carrier for damage done to the goods during
transit, in which the risk of loss but not the
property had passed to the plaintiff who was not a
party to the contract of carriage. Finally, D. & F.
Estates Ltd. v. Church Comrs. for England,
[1989] 1 A.C. 177 (H.L.) involved a claim by
tenants against a main contractor for the cost of
repairing defective plastering work performed on
premises by a sub-contractor, and a separate claim
by the occupiers of the premises for the loss of
enjoyment of use and occupation during the period
of restoration.
As is apparent in Candlewood itself (at pages
24-25) in denying recovery for pure economic
losses, the earlier decision of the House of Lords in
Junior Books Ltd. v. Veitchi Co. Ltd., [1983] A.C.
520 was carefully circumscribed, and the reason
ing of the different judges of the High Court of
Australia in Caltex Oil (Australia) Pty. Ltd. v.
The Dredge "Willemstad" (1976), 136 C.L.R. 529
was not found of assistance. The result, according
to the appellants (defendants), is that the exclu-
sionary rule survives to this day in the United
Kingdom. That much, indeed, seems apparent
from the speech of Lord Fraser of Tullybelton, at
page 17:
These two cases of Cattle, L.R. 10 Q.B. 453, and Simpson, 3
App. Cas. 279, have stood for over a hundred years and have
frequently been cited with approval in later cases, both in the
United Kingdom and elsewhere. They show, in their Lordships'
opinion, that the justification for denying a right of action to a
person who has suffered economic damage through injury to
the property of another is that for reasons of practical policy it
is considered to be inexpedient to admit his claim.
And, as his Lordship put it in remarking on Junior
Books at pages 24-25, "That case may be regarded
as having extended the scope of duty somewhat,
but any extension was not in the direction of
recognising a title to sue in a party who suffered
economic loss because his contract with the victim
of the wrong was rendered less profitable or
unprofitable."
Fundamentally, the concern expressed in these
cases is entirely practical, being directed against
the opening up of indeterminate liability as well as
the need in the law for a reasonable degree of
certainty. At the same time, there is variously
expressed a strong concern for a fair and just
result in particular cases, a concern which is per
haps mirrored in the series of rhetorical questions
(recited by my colleague) posed by Wilson J. in
Kamloops, supra, at pages 28-29. As for the
former concern, at the heart of it seems to be a
recognition that in our society at any given point
of time there are likely to be found numerous and,
indeed, complex and even pervasive sets of con
tractual relations respecting different kinds of eco
nomic activity that draw along with them the
creation of societal benefits enuring to wide seg
ments of the general population. For the law to
impose on a careless wrongdoer liability beyond
that attracted by ownership or possession of prop-
erty that is physically damaged by negligence,
including pure economic loss consequential there
on, would be to expand the ambit of liability in a
way that might seriously overburden generators of
such activity and correspondingly undermine the
range of those benefits available to the community
at large. Better that this sort of loss be left to be
insured against or allocated in some other way
under the terms of the contractual engagement,
rather than placed exclusively upon the shoulders
of a single wrongdoer. This, I conceive, may well
have been the concern of Estey J. in B.D.C. Ltd. v.
Hofstrand Farms Ltd., [1986] 1 S.C.R. 228, at
page 243 where he stated:
No doubt the courts of this country will continue to search for
reasonable and workable limits to the liability of a negligent
supplier of manufactured products or services, to the liability of
a negligent contractor for contractual undertakings owed to
others, and to the liability of persons who negligently make
misrepresentations. In this search courts will be vigilant to
protect the community from damages suffered by a breach of
the "neighbourhood" duty. At the same time, however, the
realities of modern life must be reflected by the enunciation of
a defined limit on liability capable of practical application, so
that social and commercial life can go on unimpeded by a
burden outweighing the benefit to the community of the neigh
bourhood historic principle.
That a loss to be recoverable must at all events
be foreseeable is I think well settled, but the
existence of a duty of care and, therefore, of prima
facie liability for a loss now depends on much
more than mere foreseeability. 2 I am satisfied that
the loss was foreseeable. There must also be a
sufficient proximity or neighbourhood between a
wrongdoer and a plaintiff such as gives rise to a
duty of care owed by the former to the latter. I do
not intend to canvass the origins and application of
the "neighbourhood" principle, for to do so would
be to go over once again territory already covered
by my colleague, and shall content myself with a
few remarks on the two propositions laid down by
Lord Wilberforce in Anns v. Merton London Bor-
2 Thus, in Hill v. Chief Constable of West Yorkshire, [1989]
A.C. 53 (H.L.), Lord Keith of Kinkel said, at p. 60:
(Continued on next page)
ough Council, [1978] A.C. 728 (H.L.) for deter
mining liability in negligence in the light of recent
developments. His first proposition requires that,
for determining the existence of a prima facie duty
of care, a court must ask itself whether [at page
751] "as between the alleged wrongdoer and the
person who has suffered damage there is a suffi
cient relationship of proximity or neighbourhood
such that, in the reasonable contemplation of the
former, carelessness on his part may be likely to
cause damage to the latter". Secondly, if the
answer to this question be "yes", a court must then
consider [at page 752] "whether there are any
considerations which ought to negative, or to
reduce or limit the scope of the duty or the class of
person to whom it is owed or the damages to which
a breach of it may give rise". This formulation
was, indeed, applied by the Supreme Court in
B.D.C. Ltd., supra, and Kamloops, supra.
Nowadays, in the United Kingdom, there seems
to be a developing tendency to view the Anns
formulation somewhat more narrowly than may
have been the case heretofore. In Candlewood, for
example, Lord Fraser of Tullybelton, at page 21,
drew attention to "the warning given by Lord
Keith of Kinkle in Governors of the Peabody
Donation Fund v. Sir Lindsay Parkinson & Co.
(Continued from previous page)
It has been said almost too frequently to require repetition
that foreseeability of likely harm is not in itself a sufficient
test of liability in negligence. Some further ingredient is
invariably needed to establish the requisite proximity of
relationship between plaintiff and defendant, and all the
circumstances of the case must be carefully considered and
analysed in order to ascertain whether such an ingredient is
present. The nature of the ingredient will be found to vary in
a number of different categories of decided cases.
And in Yeun Kun Yeu v. Attorney-General of Hong Kong,
[1988] A.C. 175 (P.C.), per Lord Keith of Kinkel, at p. 192:
Foreseeability of harm is a necessary ingredient of such a
relationship, but it is not the only one. Otherwise there would
be liability in negligence on the part of one who sees another
about to walk over a cliff with his head in the air, and
forebears to shout a warning.
Ltd., [1985] A.C. 210, at page 240 of the need to
resist the temptation to treat these passages from
Lord Wilberforce's speech as being of a definitive
character", and added that they are "in any event
not directly applicable to the facts of the instant
appeal, because none of the trilogy of cases
referred to by Lord Wilberforce was dealing with
claims against a wrongdoer by a person who was
not the victim of his negligence but by a third
party whose only relation to the victim was con
tractual". What I am able to discern from these
and other recent English cases' is that, fundamen
tally, the existence of a duty of care is to be
determined on the exclusive application of the first
of these two propositions, the second being con
fined to any matter of policy for denying recovery
notwithstanding that a duty of care has been found
to exist.
While numerous cases have come before the
courts in which claims for pure economic loss have
been allowed or rejected, it would seem that a
proper understanding of the problem facing us
may require an appreciation of what the decided
cases actually stand for, particularly those where
recovery was allowed. I have already mentioned
the two English cases on which the exclusionary
rule is founded, and also the first two of the three
most recent decisions of the House of Lords and
the Privy Council upholding the rule. All four of
these fall into the same general category, i.e. pure
economic loss arising from an interference with a
subsisting contractual relationship between a
plaintiff and the owner or possessor of property
injured by a defendant wrongdoer. So too does the
Australian case of Caltex, supra, allowing recov
ery of such a loss. In other cases, falling into
entirely separate categories, pure economic loss
was also allowed: e.g. Hedley Byrne & Co. Ltd. v.
Heller & Partners Ltd., [1964] A.C. 465 (H.L.);
and Haig v. Bamford et al., [1977] 1 S.C.R. 466
(reliance on negligent misstatement); Rivtow,
supra (manufacturer's failure to warn); Kam-
loops, supra (municipal authority's neglect of
3 See e.g. Yeun Kun Yeu v. Attorney-General of Hong Kong,
supra, footnote 2, per Lord Keith of Kinkel, at pp. 190-192.
statutory duty); and Ross v. Caunters, [1980] Ch.
297 (solicitor's liability).
Having said this, as seems particularly apparent
from the first of the three recent English cases
(Candlewood, supra) and restated in the second
(Aliakmon, supra), in the United Kingdom at
least a claim for pure economic loss arising from
interference with contractual rights is not recover
able. Although, as I have pointed out, the authori
ties in this country have expressed concern with
respect to the problem of indeterminate liability in
cases of pure economic loss, no binding authority
has as yet gone the length of the House of Lords.
Rather, on the basis of the decided cases here, it
would seem that the important inquiry is whether
a relationship of proximity existed between the
appellants (defendants) and the respondent (plain-
tiff) such as gave rise to a duty of care owed by the
former to the latter. This approach was accepted
by Blackburn J. in Cattle itself where, in quoting
the words of Coleridge J. in Lumley v. Gye (1853),
2 El. & Bl. 216 (Q.B.), he observed that the courts
have imposed on themselves "redressing only the
proximate and direct consequences of wrongful
acts". Ritchie J. limited his criticism of this test in
Rivtow, supra, when he stated at pages 1211-1212:
Mr. Justice Blackburn's thinking in this instance appears to me
to be controlled by the then current notions as to proximity and
remoteness of damage and I think that his approach requires
reassessment in light of the judgment in M'Alister (Donoghue)
v. Stevenson ....
It was the approach taken by Estey J. in Hofs-
trand, supra, in rejecting a claim for pure econom
ic loss.
We are not here concerned with the liability of
all users of the railway bridge as was the case in
Gypsum Carrier Inc. v. The Queen, [1978] 1 F.C.
147 (T.D.), but only with the use being made of it
by the respondent (plaintiff) at the time of the
collision. In any case, the evidence before us sug
gests that the agreements with the railway compa
nies for use of the bridge were not, as was found to
be so in that case (at page 152) "substantially the
same in meaning and effect" for, as my colleague
Mr. Justice MacGuigan points out, the agreement
to which the respondent (plaintiff) was a party
contained a feature which was not present in the
other user agreements. Furthermore, and not with
out some significance, the respondent (plaintiff)
was found at trial to have provided the bridge
owner without charge consultative services of a
full-time engineer.
In his submissions, Mr. Lowry challenged both
reliance on the Trial Judge's factual conclusions
[(1989), 49 C.C.L.T. 1; 26 F.T.R. 81, at page 28
C.C.L.T.] that:
1. The probability of the Cdn. National Railway as a dis
tinct legal person as opposed to it being merely a member of a
group, suffering the loss which it claims, was not only foresee
able but was actually known to the defendants.
2. The precise nature of the economic loss was also not only
foreseeable but was actually known.
3. The damage has been caused and is by no means indefi
nite either as to quantum or as to time.
4. There exists a sufficient proximity or close relationship
between the loss claimed and the tortious act.
5. The property of the Cdn. National Railway is not only in
close proximity to the bridge but the latter constitutes an
essential link between the Cdn. National Railway tracks on
each side of the river, without which that property cannot be
properly enjoyed by the claimant.
as well as the validity of the elements he con
sidered important in finding liability for pure eco
nomic loss, (at pages 28-29 C.C.L.T.):
1. Knowledge of the claimant as a specific individual or
identity who is likely to suffer the damage as opposed to
knowledge of a general or unascertained class of people.
2. Not only must it be established that loss was probably
foreseeable but the precise nature of the loss should have been
foreseeable.
3. There must be a sufficient degree of proximity between
the act committed by the tortfeasor and the injury complained
of, that an ordinary right-thinking person would feel that the
tortfeasor is morally bound to compensate the victim (Caltex
Oil Australian Property Ltd. v. the Dredge Willemstad). This
has also been expressed in terms of sufficient proximity of the
property to lead to a duty of care to the claimant.
In my judgment, taken collectively, if not, perhaps,
individually, 4 these elements demonstrate that suf
ficient proximity giving rise to a duty of care owed
by the appellants (defendants) to the respondent
(plaintiff) existed; the case is a compelling one for
recovery of the loss claimed. In the exceptional
circumstances of this case, I can find no reason in
policy for negativing this duty or for denying
recovery of the loss. In so saying I wish once more
to emphasize that the issue before us is solely
concerned with liability for pure economic loss
suffered by the respondent (plaintiff) and not at
all with claims of the same nature advanced by
other users of the bridge.
Finally, as the decided cases also show, the
challenge of formulating a principle of general
application for cases of this kind having a "defined
limit on liability capable of practical application" 5
has proven to be both elusive and daunting, and it
is not at all easy to see the future shape such a
formulation might take or even, indeed, that one
will soon emerge. Nonetheless, I am minded of the
optimism expressed by Sir Robert Megarry V.-C.
in Ross v. Caunters, supra, at page 321:
I am content—indeed, happy—to leave it to other courts in
other cases on other facts to evolve the test or tests that have to
be applied. In some cases there may be not much more than the
"feel" of the case to point to the answer. But enough decisions
in enough cases must sooner or later make possible the induc-
In Caltex, supra, there is found some support for the notion
that knowledge by a wrongdoer of a claimant as a specific
individual as a suitable test of proximity and therefore of duty
(see the judgments of Gibbs J., at p. 555 and of Mason J., at p.
593), but this was rejected in Candlewood, supra, at p. 24 as
lacking in logic. Here in Canada, Dickson J. (as he then was) at
p. 476 of Haig v. Bamford, supra, considered such a test "too
narrow", while Wilson J. at p. 31 of City of Kamloops, supra,
expressed some scepticism as to its adequacy, saying that while
such a test "may make the class determinate ... it gives no
guarantee that it will be small". As I see it, a problem with this
test, taken by itself, is that it could unduly limit liability where
there are no rational grounds for so doing, or expand it
considerably for knowledgeable defendants but not otherwise.
5 B.D.C. Ltd. v. Hofstrand Farms Ltd., supra, per Estey J.,
at p. 243.
tive process of laying down a test or tests by which all may be
guided.
I would dismiss this appeal with costs.
The following are the reasons for judgment
rendered in English by
MACGUIGAN J.A.: This is an appeal by the
owner and master of the tug Jervis Crown from a
judgment of Addy J. [(1989), 49 C.C.L.T. 1; 26
F.T.R. 81] awarding the plaintiff/respondent
Canadian National Railway Company ("CNR")
damages in tort for economic loss arising from a
collision between a log barge in tow of the tug and
a bridge owned by Public Works Canada
("PWC") and used by CNR to cross the Fraser
River at New Westminster, British Columbia.
PWC had no insurance on the bridge, and there
were no grants in lieu of taxes paid on it.
Negligence as to the collision with the bridge
was admitted, and, there being no claims for
freight revenue lost but solely for additional costs
of operation, CNR and two other railways were
awarded the costs incurred in rerouting their trains
upriver across a Canadian Pacific Limited bridge
and tracks en route to and from Vancouver.
The courts have often contrasted direct injury to
property with what is frequently called pure eco
nomic loss, which was defined by Estey J. in
Attorney General for Ontario v. Fatehi, [1984] 2
S.C.R. 536, at page 542, as follows:
By "pure economic loss" the courts have usually been taken to
refer to a diminution of worth incurred without any physical
injury to any asset of the plaintiff.
Professor Bruce Feldthusen, "Pure Economic Loss
Consequent Upon Physical Damage to a Third
Party" (1977), 16 U.W.O.L. Rev. 1 at page 4,
distinguishes pure economic loss from consequen
tial economic loss as follows:
Consequential economic loss is a financial loss which by defini
tion is always claimed by the same party who has suffered
physical damage. It is a loss one suffers because one has
suffered physical damage.... Pure economic loss is a financial
loss which is not consequent upon injury to the plaintiff's own
person or property.
Professor P. S. Atiyah, "Negligence and Economic
Loss" (1967), 83 L.Q. Rev. 248, at page 265, has
referred to damages which can be recovered for
pecuniary loss as "parasitic on some physical
damage done to the plaintiff himself".
There has been what Professor John G. Flem-
ing, The Law of Torts, 7th ed. at page 162, has
called "ingrained opposition" to recovery for pure
economic loss on the ground that (at page 163)
"the burden of compensating anyone besides the
primary casualty is feared to be unduly oppressive
because most accidents are bound to entail reper
cussions, great or small, upon all with whom he
had family, business or other valuable relations."
In the words of Professor Feldthusen (at page 26):
The major difficulty with pure economic loss ... is that for
each occurrence of physical damage, a potentially large or
indefinite class may experience foreseeable economic loss. In
those circumstances the plaintiff may be the cheapest cost-
avoider, and the costs of shifting the loss to the tortfeasor will
increase as the poll of potential plaintiffs is expanded.
The sole question on this appeal is whether the
Trial Judge was correct in holding that the appel
lants could be held liable in negligence for such
pure economic loss in the absence of any physical
damage to CNR's property.
I
The New Westminster Railway Bridge, which
spans the Fraser River between Surrey and New
Westminster, was built in 1904 and is owned,
operated and maintained by Her Majesty the
Queen in right of Canada, represented by the
Minister of Public Works. It carries a single rail
way track. Its sole purpose is to service railway
traffic, both passenger and freight, but it incorpo-
rates a swing span to permit marine traffic to
navigate the waterway.
The commercial marine traffic transiting the
Fraser River through the swing span is substantial.
On November 28, 1987, while being towed down
stream by the tug in heavy fog, the barge collided
with the bridge, causing extensive damage to it,
which necessitated its closure for several weeks
while repairs were made. The appellants admitted
liability for negligence as to the collision itself.
During the down-time for the bridge the rail
ways had to reroute traffic over another bridge
farther upstream. Freight was either delayed or
not transported at all. The use of the waterway
was also interfered with, and cargo was delayed
and/or transported by land.
Four railways were, by contract with PWC,
licensed to use the bridge. All of the operating
costs of the bridge are recovered from the four
railways, with PWC making neither profit nor loss
from its operation.
Of the four railways CNR was the principal
user, accounting for 85-86% of the railway cars
using the bridge in 1988. On the average it sent
across 32 trains with 1,530 cars a day. CNR
therefore bore the principal burden of the conse
quential losses resulting from the accident.
The smallest railway user, Canadian Pacific
Limited did not participate in the litigation. Before
trial there was an agreement that the entitlement
of the other two railways, the Burlington Northern
Railway and the B.C. Power and Hydro Authority
Railway, to recovery for pure economic loss would
stand or fall on the result of the CNR's claim. It is
therefore only the CNR claim which is directly in
issue on this appeal. There is, nevertheless, an
extra clause in the CNR's licence agreement with
PWC which is not found in the other such agree-
ments. This provision, clause 10, is as follows
(Appeal Book at pages 158-159):
The Railway agrees that it will:
(a) in the case of emergency, (as determined by Canada),
and upon request of Canada, proceed to make such repairs,
changes, or alterations to the Bridge, or maintenance thereof,
including without limiting the generality of the foregoing, the
approaches thereto, the wooden trestles, steel superstruc
tures, (including the swing span) thereof and the signal
system thereof, (including the interlocking plant therefor), as
are absolutely necessary, in the opinion of Canada, for the
safe and proper operation of the Bridge, (including all ap
proaches thereto), and that Canada shall reimburse the
Railway the reasonable cost of making such repairs, changes,
alterations, or maintenance in accordance with accounts
rendered therefor from time to time to Canada by the
Railway; PROVIDED HOWEVER, that no such repairs,
changes, alterations or maintenance shall be made or carried
out until Canada approves a Memorandum of Understanding
to this agreement, setting out the nature of the repairs,
changes, alterations or maintenance required to be done, the
details of the work to be performed in relation thereto, and
the basis of payment therefor; and
(b) upon the written request of Canada from time to time,
provide to Canada consulting services or inspections related
to the planning, design and construction of the Bridge;
PROVIDED HOWEVER that no such services or inspections
shall be performed or made until Canada approves a Memo
randum of Understanding to this agreement, setting out the
nature of the services or inspections to be performed, the
details thereof and the basis of payment therefor; and
(c) upon the written request of Canada from time to time,
perform such maintenance and repairs to the signal system
and interlocking plant of the Bridge as are requested; PRO
VIDED HOWEVER that no such maintenance or repairs shall
be made or carried out until Canada approves a Memoran
dum of Understanding to this agreement, setting out the
nature of the maintenance and repairs required to be done,
the details of the work to be performed in relation thereto,
and the basis of payment therefor.
The Trial Judge's conclusions as to the facts,
which were not challenged before us, were as
follows (at pages 26-28 C.C.L.T.):
1. The New Westminster bridge was designed and used
exclusively for rail traffic.
2. The Cdn. National Railway has used it continuously since
1915 and it constitutes an integral part of the railway's main
line and is in effect the connecting link between the Vancouver
terminus and the main line. It constitutes the sole direct link
between the Cdn. National Railway tracks on the north and on
the south shores of the main arm of the Fraser.
3. The bridge is entirely owned by P.W.C. but is used by
four railways pursuant to license agreements with P.W.C.
under which they pay a toll for each railway car that crosses
the bridge. The toll is fixed in such a way as to cover the entire
cost of operation of the bridge.
4. The license agreements are identical except that the Cdn.
National Railway agreement has an extra clause whereby the
Cdn. National Railway is to provide P.W.C. with such services
as emergency repairs, changes, alterations and maintenance,
consulting inspection and planning services, maintenance and
repairs (other than routine matters), pertaining to the signal
system, frogs and the interlocking plant.
5. Consulting services are provided to P.W.C. without
charge by a full-time engineer employed by the Cdn. National
Railway, whose sole duties involve the Westminster Railway
bridge and two other railway bridges in the vicinity which
belong to that railway.
6. The Cdn. National Railway periodically arranges without
charge for a complete inspection of the girders, stringers and
other metal portions of the bridge and also uses its "sperry" car
to inspect the rails.
7. At times, Cdn. National Railway provides materials for
the bridge. Following the collision, it supplied P.W.C. without
charge with a large girder to assist the jacking up of the swing
span, thus saving several days of bridge closure.
8. When the bridge is closed for routine maintenance, the
timing and duration are negotiated and arranged between the
Cdn. National Railway and P.W.C.
9. More than 86 per cent of the cars crossing the bridge
belong to the Cdn. National Railway and all of the defendants
were fully aware of the fact that the Cdn. National Railway
was the primary user.
10. Captain MacDonnel, the master of the JERVIS
CROWN and other masters and seamen operating in the river
commonly refer, to the bridge from time to time as the C.N.
Rail bridge. Captain MacDonnel himself had been familiar
with the bridge for over 40 years and until sometime after the
collision actually believed that it belonged to the Cdn. National
Railway.
11. All of the defendants knew that the port Mann-Thornton
marshalling and switching yard of the Cdn. National Railway,
which is the main switching yard for the greater Vancouver
area, is situated approximately 1 1/2 miles up-river from the
bridge on the south bank of the Fraser.
12. The defendants knew that there was no other rail bridge
over the main arm of the river below the Westminster bridge
and, because the bridge had been damaged previously, they also
knew that in the event of a closure of the bridge due to damage,
the Cdn. National Railway would have to detour over the Cdn.
Pacific Railway bridge upriver between Mission and Matsqui
and divert over the Cdn. Pacific Railway tracks on the north
bank of the Fraser.
13. The Cdn. National Railway is not claiming for loss of
freight business but only for the actual costs incurred by reason
of the bridge closure.
Immediately following his findings on the facts,
the learned Trial Judge proceeded to draw his
conclusions (at pages 28-29 C.C.L.T.):
The following conclusions arise from these facts:
1. The probability of the Cdn. National Railway as a dis
tinct legal person as opposed to it being merely a member of a
group, suffering the loss which it claims, was not only foresee
able but was actually known to the defendants.
2. The precise nature of the economic loss was also not only
foreseeable but was actually known.
3. The damage has been caused and is by no means indefi
nite either as to quantum or as to time.
4. There exists a sufficient proximity or close relationship
between the loss claimed and the tortious act.
5. The property of the Cdn. National Railway is not only in
close proximity to the bridge but the latter constitutes an
essential link between the Cdn. National Railway tracks on
each side of the river, without which that property cannot be
properly enjoyed by the claimant.
It is neither necessary nor would it be desirable to attempt to
formulate a set of rules which would apply to all cases where
pure economic loss would be recoverable. However, the follow
ing requirements seem to me to be important, if one is to avoid
opening the floodgates to crippling litigation:
1. Knowledge of the claimant as a specific individual or
identity who is likely to suffer the damage as opposed to
knowledge of a general or unascertained class of people.
2. Not only must it be established that loss was probably
foreseeable but the precise nature of the loss should have been
foreseeable.
3. There must be a sufficient degree of proximity between
the act committed by the tortfeasor and the injury complained
of, that an ordinary right-thinking person would feel that the
tortfeasor is morally bound to compensate the victim (Caltex
Oil Australian Property Ltd. v. the Dredge Willemstad). This
has also been expressed in terms of sufficient proximity of the
property to lead to a duty of care to the claimant.
It has also been suggested in certain cases that the tortfeasor
should not be exposed to liability out of all proportion to his
wrong or moral culpability and that the degree of negligence,
lack of care of recklessness should be considered as a factor. In
other cases it has been stated that the economic loss must not
overshadow that caused by the physical injury, or damage.
Allowing recovery of economic loss to the Cdn. National
Railway in this case would neither involve compensation in an
indeterminate amount, nor for an indeterminate time nor to an
indeterminate class. In the circumstances, I have no difficulty
in finding that the defendants owed a duty to the Cdn. National
Railway to refrain from damaging the bridge which they well
knew was constantly used by the latter as an integral part of its
railway system, it being clearly foreseeable that the offending
conduct involved an unreasonably great risk of harm to the
claimant.
The Cdn. National Railway will therefore be entitled to
recover its economic loss as claimed.
II
The state of the English authorities on the ques
tion of liability for economic loss is such that in the
most recent pronouncement of the House of Lords
on the subject in D. & F. Estates Ltd. v. Church
Comrs. for England, [1989] 1 A.C. 177, at page
201, Lord Bridge of Harwich plaintively remarked
that "the authorities, as it seems to me, speak with
such an uncertain voice that, no matter how
searching the analysis to which they are subject,
they yield no clear and conclusive answer."
Another observer describes the law as a "conceptu-
al morass" in which "The pendulum is swinging
wildly and is yet to find a regular rhythm": Peter
Cane, "Economic Loss in Tort: Is the Pendulum
Out of Control?" (1989), 52 Mod. L. Rev. 200 at
page 214.
Nevertheless, a frequently accepted starting
point for an analysis of economic loss is the obser
vation of Lord Wilberforce with its two proposi
tions, given for the majority of the House, in Anns
v. Merton London Borough Council, [1978] A.C.
728 (H.L.), at pages 751-752:
Through the trilogy of cases in this House—Donoghue v.
Stevenson [1932] A.C. 562, Hedley Byrne & Co. Ltd. v. Heller
& Partners Ltd. [1964] A.C. 465, and Dorset Yacht Co. Ltd. v.
Home Office [1970] A.C. 1004, the position has now been
reached that in order to establish that a duty of care arises in a
particular situation, it is not necessary to bring the facts of that
situation within those of previous situations in which a duty of
care has been held to exist. Rather the question has to be
approached in two stages. First one has to ask whether, as
between the alleged wrongdoer and the person who has suffered
damage there is a sufficient relationship of proximity or neigh
bourhood such that, in the reasonable contemplation of the
former, carelessness on his part may be likely to cause damage
to the latter—in which case a prima facie duty of care arises.
Secondly, if the first question is answered affirmatively, it is
necessary to consider whether there are any considerations
which ought to negative, or to reduce or limit the scope of the
duty or the class of person to whom it is owed or the damages
to which a breach of it may give rise: see Dorset Yacht case
[1970] A.C. 1004, per Lord Reid at p. 1027. Examples of this
are Hedley Byrne's case [1964] A.0 465 where the class of
potential plaintiffs was reduced to those shown to have relied
upon the correctness of statements made, and Weller & Co. v.
Foot and Mouth Disease Research Institute [1966] 1 Q.B. 569;
and (I cite these merely as illustrations, without discussion)
cases about "economic loss" where, a duty having been held to
exist, the nature of the recoverable damages was limited: see
S.C.M. (United Kingdom) Ltd. v. W. J. Whittall & Son Ltd.
[1971] 1 Q.B. 337 and Spartan Steel & Alloys Ltd. v. Martin
& Co. (Contractors) Ltd. [1973] Q.B. 27. [Emphasis added.]
In Donoghue v. Stevenson, [1932] A.C. 562
(H.L.), at page 580, Lord Atkin had laid down the
basic principles of modern negligence law:
You must take reasonable care to avoid acts or omissions which
you can reasonably foresee would be likely to injure your
neighbour. Who, then, in law is my neighbour? The answer
seems to be—persons who are so closely and directly affected
by my act that I ought reasonably to have them in contempla
tion as being as affected when I am directing my mind to the
acts or omissions which are called in question.
Dorset Yacht Co. Ltd. v. Home Office, [1970]
A.C. 1004 (H.L.), where seven Borstal boys had
damaged a yacht in an escape attempt in another
yacht, was treated by the House of Lords as a
direct application of Donoghue v. Stevenson. It is
the third case in the trilogy, Hedley Byrne & Co.
Ltd. v. Heller & Partners Ltd., [1964] A.C. 465
(H.L.), which, in relation to pure economic loss,
requires a closer scrutiny.
From the time of Cattle v. Stockton Water
works Company (1875), L.R. 10 Q.B. 453, it was
generally believed that pecuniary loss is not recov
erable in the law of negligence absent physical
injury or damage. This exclusionary rule, as it has
often been called, was considered to have survived
the extension of the range of negligence by the
good neighbour principle of Donoghue v. Steven-
son. Professor Bruce Feldthusen, Economic Negli
gence, 2nd ed., (Toronto: Carswell, 1989), at page
200 believes that the case law supports a firm
exclusionary rule which he states as follows:
The recovery of pure economic loss will be precluded in negli
gence when it is consequent upon an injury to the person or
property of a third person. 6
Professor J. A. Smillie, "Negligence and economic
loss" (1982), 32 U.T.L.J. 231, says [at page 231]
that "Prior to 1963 [i.e. Hedley Byrne], a rule
denying liability in negligence for purely economic
loss . . . had been applied consistently for almost
ninety years." The rationale for the exclusionary
rule was most pithily expressed in an oft-quoted
phrase of Cardozo C.J. in Ultramares Corporation
v. Touche, 255 N.Y. 170, at page 179, 174 N.E.
441 (Ct. App. 1931) at page 444, where he
described recovery for pure economic loss as "a
liability in an indeterminate amount for an
indeterminate time to an indeterminate class."
In Hedley Byrne, however, the House of Lords
held that a negligent misrepresentation may give
rise to an action for damages for financial loss
(although the defendant was found not liable on
the facts because of an express disclaimer of re
sponsibility). Lord Devlin in particular went very
far in striking at the exclusionary rule (at
page 517):
... the distinction is now said to depend on whether financial
loss is caused through physical injury or whether it is caused
directly. The interposition of the physical injury is said to make
a difference of principle. I can find neither logic nor common
sense in this. If irrespective of contract, a doctor negligently
advises a patient that he can safely pursue his occupation and
he cannot and the patient's health suffers and he loses his
livelihood, the patient has a remedy. But if the doctor negli
gently advises him that he cannot safely pursue his occupation
when in fact he can and he loses his livelihood, there is said to
be no remedy. Unless, of course, the patient was a private
patient and the doctor accepted half a guinea for his trouble:
then the patient can recover all. I am bound to say, my Lords,
that I think this to be nonsense.
Lord Devlin and Lord Hodson both relied on
Morrison Steamship Co., Ld. v. Greystoke Castle
(Cargo Owners), [1947] A.C. 265 (H.L.), and
Lord Hodson put the issue this way (at page 509):
6 Although Professor Feldthusen believes that the exclusion-
ary rule is "firm", he acknowledges that it is "subject to a
number of specific exceptions".
It is difficult to see why liability as such should depend on
the nature of the damage. Lord Roche in Morrison Steamship
Co. Ltd. v. Greystoke Castle (Cargo Owners) instanced damage
to a lorry by the negligence of the driver of another lorry which,
while it does no damage to the goods in the second lorry, causes
the goods owner to be put to expense which is recoverable by
direct action against the negligent driver.
Lord Pearce (at page 536) cited Greystoke Castle
as authority for the proposition that "economic
loss alone, without some physical or material
damage to support it, can afford a cause of
action".
Hedley Byrne was greatly relied upon by the
High Court of Australia in Caltex Oil (Australia)
Pty. Ltd. v. The Dredge "Willemstad" (1976), 11
A.L.R. 227, in allowing recovery for economic
loss. In that case a dredge, while deepening a
shipping channel in Botany Bay, had broken an
underwater pipeline which carried petroleum prod
ucts from a refinery (the owners of which owned
the pipeline) on the southern shore to plaintiff's oil
terminal on the northern shore. The plaintiff sup
plied the crude oil to the refinery for processing,
and retained notional ownership in the oil being
refined and owned the products actually passing
through the pipeline. The Court unanimously
(although with a different rationalization for each
of the five Judges) allowed recovery for the costs
of arranging alternative means of transporting
petroleum products until the pipeline was repaired.
Gibbs J., although acknowledging that subse
quent authorities have not regarded Hedley Byrne
as obliterating the distinction between damages for
pecuniary loss and damages for material or physi
cal loss, wrote (at page 245):
In my opinion it is still right to say that as a general rule
damages are not recoverable for economic loss which is not
consequential upon injury to the plaintiff's person or property.
The fact that the loss was foreseeable is not enough to make it
recoverable. However, there are exceptional cases in which the
defendant has knowledge or means of knowledge that the
plaintiff individually, and not merely as a member of an
unascertained class, will be likely to suffer economic loss as a
consequence of his negligence, and owes the plaintiff a duty to
take care not to cause him such damage by his negligent act. It
is not necessary, and would not be wise, to attempt to formulate
a principle that would cover all cases in which such a duty is
owed; to borrow the words of Lord Diplock in Mutual Life &
Citizens' Assurance Co Ltd v Evatt [1971] 1 All ER 150;
[1971] AC 793 at 809: "Those will fall to be ascertained step
by step as the facts of particular cases which come before the
courts make it necessary to determine them." All the facts of
the particular case will have to be considered. It will be
material, but not in my opinion sufficient, that some property
of the plaintiff was in physical proximity to the damaged
property, or that the plaintiff, and the person whose property
was injured, were engaged in a common adventure.
Stephen J. (at page 259) spoke of "The need, in
cases of purely economic loss, for some further
control of liability apart from that offered by the
concept of reasonable foreseeability", and opined
(at page 260) that "in the general realm of negli
gent conduct it may be that no more specific
proposition can be formulated than a need for
insistence upon sufficient proximity between tor-
tious act and compensable detriment". He added
(at page 261):
Some guidance in the determination of the requisite degree
of proximity will be derived from the broad principle which
underlies liability in negligence. As Lord Atkin put it in a much
cited passage from his speech in Donoghue v Stevenson ([1932]
AC at 580; [1932] All ER Rep at 11) the liability for negli
gence "is no doubt based upon a general public sentiment of
moral wrongdoing for which the offender must pay". Such a
sentiment will only be present when there exists a degree of
proximity between the tortious act and the injury such that the
community will recognize the tortfeasor as being in justice
obliged to make good his moral wrongdoing by compensating
the victims of his negligence. Again, as Lord Morris said in the
Dorset Yacht Case ([1970] AC at 1039), courts may have
recourse to a consideration of what is "fair and reasonable" in
determining whether in particular circumstances a duty of care
arises; so too, I would suggest, in determining the requisite
degree of proximity before there may be recovery for purely
economic loss.
As the body precedent accumulates some general area of
demarcation between what is and is not a sufficient degree of
proximity in any particular class of case of economic loss will
no doubt emerge; but its emergence neither can be, nor should
it be, other than as a reflection of the piecemeal conclusions
arrived at in precedent cases.
The salient features for establishing sufficient
proximity in the case he found to be fivefold: (1)
the defendants' knowledge that damage was inher-
ently likely to produce the kind of consequential
economic loss which occurred; (2) their knowl
edge, from charts, of the existence of the pipeline
and of its use by the plaintiff; (3) the fact that
damage was negligently caused to the property of
the pipeline owner; (4) the nature of the detriment
suffered, i.e., the loss of use of the pipeline; and (5)
the fact that the claim was not for loss of profits
but for the direct consequence of the expense
incurred in employing alternative modes of
transport.
Mason J. found liability in the fact that the
defendants could reasonably foresee "that a specif
ic individual, as distinct from a general class of
persons" (at page 274) would suffer financial loss
as a consequence of his conduct.
Jacobs J. opted for a "physical propinquity"
test, provided only that there is a physical effect
(which he distinguishes from physical injury) on
property of the plaintiff. However, since he linked
this physical propinquity of the plaintiff's property
to the place where the defendant's act or omission
had its physical effect, it appears that he would
have limited recovery to the plaintiff's crude oil
and products at the refinery at the time of the
incident, absent the agreement of the parties as to
the amount of damages.
Murphy J. appears to have rejected the exclu-
sionary rule entirely.
Returning to House of Lords' decisions, one
finds the high point for what I may call Lord
Devlin's point of view in Junior Books Ltd. v.
Veitchi Co. Ltd., [1983] A.C. 520, a Scots appeal
where, after a floor laid by the defenders had
cracked, the pursuers sued for damages including
the cost of relaying the floor and various items of
economic and financial loss consequential upon
replacement, such as the cost of removal of ma
chinery and loss of profits during relaying. It was
not alleged that the state of the floor gave rise to
any danger of injury to people or property in the
factory. That the majority of the House put the
recovery allowed upon wide grounds is evident
from the speech of Lord Roskill (at page 539):
My Lords, I think there is no doubt that Donoghue v.
Stevenson . . by its insistence upon proximity, in the sense in
which Lord Atkin used that word, as the foundation of the duty
of care which was there enunciated, marked a great develop
ment in the law of delict and of negligence alike .... But that
advance having been thus made in 1932, the doctrine then
enunciated was at first confined by judicial decision within
relatively narrow limits....Though initially there is no doubt
that because of Lord Atkin's phraseology in Donoghue v.
Stevenson . "injury to the consumer's life or property," it was
thought that the duty of care did not extend beyond avoiding
physical injury or physical damage to the person or the prop
erty of the person to whom the duty of care was owed, that
limitation has long since ceased ....
And again, in the context of Lord Wilberforce's
second proposition in Anns (at page 546):
... the only suggested reason for limiting the damage (ex
hypothesi economic or financial only) recoverable for the
breach of the duty of care just enunciated is that hitherto the
law has not allowed such recovery and therefore ought not in
the future to do so. My Lords, with all respect to those who find
this a sufficient answer, I do not. I think this is the next logical
step forward in the development of this branch of the law. I see
no reason why what was called during the argument "damage
to the pocket" simpliciter should be disallowed when "damage
to the pocket" coupled with physical damage has hitherto
always been allowed. I do not think that this development, if
development it be, will lead to untoward consequences. The
concept of proximity [used to establish the duty of care under
Lord Wilberforce's first proposition] must always involve, at
least in most cases, some degree of reliance—I have already
mentioned the words "skill" and "judgment" ...
Lord Brandon of Oakbrook in dissent said (at page
551):
The effect of accepting the respondents' contention with regard
to the scope of the duty of care involved would be, in substance,
to create, as between two persons who are not in any contractu
al relationship with each other, obligations of one of those two
persons to the other which are only really appropriate as
between persons who do have such a relationship between them.
He went on (at page 552) to warn against "the
inherent difficulty of seeking to impose what are
really contractual obligations by unprecedented
and, as I think, wholly undesirable extensions of
the existing law of delict."
In the light of the recent trilogy of House of
Lords/Privy Council cases, Junior Books seems
less a "landmark decision" than "an anomaly, to
be distinguished, restricted and eventually
forgotten".' In the first of these recent decisions,
Candlewood Navigation Corpn. Ltd. v. Mitsui
O.S.K. Lines Ltd. ["The Mineral Transporter"J,
[1986] A.C. 1 (P.C.), where it was held that a
time charterer could not recover damages for
pecuniary loss caused by damage to the chartered
vessel by a third party, Lord Fraser of Tullybelton,
who had participated in the majority view in
Junior Books, contented himself with distinguish
ing that case on the ground that its extension of
the scope of duty "was not in the direction of
recognising a title to sue in a party who suffered
economic loss because his contract with the victim
of the wrong was rendered less profitable or
unprofitable" [at pages 24-25]. He saved his real
fire for Caltex (at page 24):
Their Lordships have carefully considered these reasons for
the decision in the Caltex case, 136 C.L.R. 529. With regard to
the reasons given by Gibbs and Mason JJ., their Lordships have
difficulty in seeing how to distinguish between a plaintiff as an
individual and a plaintiff as a member of an unascertained
class. The test can hardly be whether the plaintiff is known by
name to the wrongdoer. Nor does it seem logical for the test to
depend upon the plaintiff being a single individual. Further,
why should there be a distinction for this purpose between a
case where the wrongdoer knows (or has the means of knowing)
that the persons likely to be affected by his negligence consist
of a definite number of persons whom he can identify either by
name or in some other way (for example as being the owners of
particular factories or hotels) and who may therefore be
regarded as an ascertained class, and a case where the wrong
doer knows only that there are several persons, the exact
number being to him unknown, and some or all of whom he
could not identify by name or otherwise, and who may there
fore be regarded as an unascertained class? Moreover much of
the argument in favour of an ascertained class seems to depend
upon the view that the class would normally consist of only a
few individuals. But would it be different if the class, though
ascertained, was large? Suppose for instance that the class
The phrases are taken from Feldthusen, "Economic Loss:
Where Are We Going After Junior Books?" (1987), 12 Can.
Bus. L.J. 241 at p. 273. A generally similar point of view was
expressed in the same symposium by Professor Joost Blom,
"Economic Loss: Curbs on the Way Ahead?" (1987), 12 Can.
Bus. L.J. 275.
consisted of all the pupils in a particular school. If it was a
kindergarten school with only six pupils they might be regarded
as constituting an ascertained class, even if their names were
unknown to the wrongdoer. If the school was a large one with
over a thousand pupils it might be suggested that they were not
an ascertained class. But it is not easy to see a distinction in
principle merely because the number of possible claimants is
larger in one case than in the other. Apart from cases of
negligent misstatement, with which their Lordships are not
here concerned, they do not consider that it is practicable by
reference to an ascertained class to find a satisfactory control
mechanism which could be applied in such a way as to give
reasonable certainty in its results.
Similarly they are, with the utmost respect to Stephen J., not
able to find in his speech a statement of principle which
appears to them to offer a satisfactory and reasonably certain
guide. The opinion of Jacobs J. does appear to their Lordships
to provide a reasonably certain test, namely the traditional test
of physical propinquity. But that gives no support to the
argument presented by Mr. Gleeson.
In these circumstances their Lordships have concluded that
they are entitled, and indeed bound, to reach their own decision
without the assistance of any single ratio decidendi to be found
in the Caltex case.
Nevertheless, in reasserting the exclusionary
rule he found a small niche for Caltex (at
page 25):
Their Lordships consider that some limit or control mech
anism has to be imposed upon the liability of a wrongdoer
towards those who have suffered economic damage in conse
quence of his negligence. The need for such a limit has been
repeatedly asserted in the cases, from Cattle's case ... to
Caltex, . . . and their Lordships are not aware that a view to the
contrary has ever been judicially expressed. The policy of
imposing such a limit is consistent with the policy of limiting
the liability of ships and aircraft in maritime and aviation law
by statute and by international agreement .... Not only has
that rule been generally accepted in many countries including
the United Kingdom, Canada, the United States of America
and until now Australia, but it has the merit of drawing a
definite and readily ascertainable line. It should enable legal
practitioners to advise their clients as to their rights with
reasonable certainty, and their Lordships are not aware of any
widespread dissatisfaction with the rule. These considerations
operate to limit the scope of the duty owned by a wrongdoer,
and they do so at the second stage mentioned by Lord Wilber-
force in the passage cited above from his speech in Anns v.
Merton London Borough Council . . . .
Almost any rule will have some exceptions, and the decision
in the Caltex case may perhaps be regarded as one of the
"exceptional cases" referred to by Gibbs J. in the passage
already quoted from his judgment. The exceptional circum
stances may be those referred to by Stephen J., . .. already
mentioned. Certainly the decision in Caltex does not appear to
have been based upon a rejection of the general rule stated in
Cattle's case.
In my view what is of capital importance is that
the Privy Council stressed the necessity for "some
limit or control mechanism", but did not adopt an
absolute rule excluding liability for pure economic
loss.
In the second decision, Leigh and Sillavan Ltd.
v. Aliakmon Shipping Co. Ltd., [1986] A.C. 785
(H.L.), where bad stowage had caused damage to
goods on shipboard, it was held that for a claim in
negligence, the plaintiff buyers had to have either
the legal ownership or a possessory title to the
goods damaged and not merely contractual rights
in relation to them. The reasons for dismissing the
claim were set forth for the House by Lord Bran-
don of Oakbrook, the dissenting judge in Junior
Books, who said (at pages 816-817 A.C.):
In any event, where a general rule, which is simple to under
stand and easy to apply, has been established by a long line of
authority over many years, I do not think that the law should
allow special pleading in a particular case within the general
rule to detract from its application. If such detraction were to
be permitted in one particular case, it would lead to attempts to
have it permitted in a variety of other particular cases, and the
result would be that the certainty, which the application of the
general rule presently provides, would be seriously undermined.
Yet certainty of the law is of the utmost importance, especially
but by no means only, in commercial matters. I therefore think
that the general rule, re-affirmed as it has been so recently by
the Privy Council in The Mineral Transporter [1986] A.C. 1,
ought to apply to a case like the present one, and that there is
nothing in what Lord Wilberforce said in Anns' case [1978]
A.C. 728 which would compel a different conclusion.
Finally in D. & F. Estates, supra, where negli
gence had occurred in plastering by subcontrac
tors, an action against the general contractors for
replastering, for the cost of cleaning carpets and
other possessions dirtied by falling plaster and for
damages for disturbance by other parties was
rejected since the losses claimed were found to be
pure economic loss. Lord Bridge of Harwick said
(the speech of Lord Oliver of Aylmerton being to
the same effect) of the majority decision in Junior
Books (at page 202):
The consensus of judicial opinion, with which I concur, seems
to be that the decision of the majority is so far dependent upon
the unique, albeit non-contractual, relationship between the
pursuer and the defender in that case and the unique scope of
the duty of care owed by the defender to the pursuer arising
from that relationship that the decision cannot be regarded as
laying down any principle of general application in the law of
tort or delict. The dissenting speech of Lord Brandon of
Oakbrook on the other hand enunciates with cogency and
clarity principles of fundamental importance which are clearly
applicable to determine the scope of the duty of care owed by
one party to another in the absence, as in the instant case, of
either any contractual relationship or any such uniquely proxi-
mate relationship as that on which the decision of the majority
in Junior Books was founded.
Lord Bridge concluded (at page 206) that once a
hidden defect in a chattel is discovered so that it is
rendered harmless, whether it is then valueless or
capable of economic repair "the economic loss is
recoverable in contract by a buyer or hirer of the
chattel entitled to the benefit of a relevant warran
ty of quality, but is not recoverable in tort by a
remote buyer or hirer of the chattel". Lord Bridge
also took comfort from the recent decision of the
United States Supreme Court in East River S.S.
Corp. v. Transamerica Delaval, Inc., 106 S. Ct.
2295 (1986), where it was held that no products-
liability claim lies in admiralty when a commercial
party alleges injury only to the product itself
resulting in purely economic loss.'
The "uncertain voice" of the English authorities
to which Lord Bridge referred in D. & F. Estates
is, I believe, now amply manifest, but I think it is
nevertheless possible to hazard certain general
conclusions. First, there is in England a strong
preference for upholding the exclusionary rule,
particularly in cases such as these involving prod
ucts liability where a claim in tort can be seen as
an end-run around limitations on contractual lia
bility (Lord Brandon in Junior Books and Leigh
and Sillavan, Lord Bridge in D. & F. Estates).
Second, there is nevertheless a recognition that
there are, at the very least, exceptional cases in
which the rule does not apply. Junior Books has
not been overruled, and the result in Caltex has
not been disapproved of. The rule cannot therefore
be regarded as absolute. Third, in these exception
al cases where liability is allowed there will be
found factors of unusual proximity or propinquity
somewhat analogous to those which under the first
of Lord Wilberforce's propositions establish the
basic criterion of duty itself (Hedley Byrne,
Caltex, Junior Books).
III
The law on pure economic loss is more open in
Canada than in England, if only because there
have been many fewer decisions, especially by the
Supreme Court of Canada. It would hardly be an
exaggeration to say that there is only one real
8 In Reid v Rush & Tompkins Group plc, [1989] 3 All ER
228 (C.A.), at p. 238, Ralph Gibson L.J., speaking for himself
alone, says of D. & F. Estates:
I think it is clear that their Lordships were not, as I
understand their speeches, dealing with the tort of negligence
in all its forms and it does not seem to me that they were
intending to lay down a rule that in no case can damages for
economic loss be recovered except under the principles estab
lished by the Hedley Byrne case. I take Lord Oliver's state
ment, namely that damages for pure economic loss cannot be
recovered unless the case can be brought within the principle
of reliance established by the Hedley Byrne case, to apply
only to the sort of case under consideration in D & F Estates
v Church Cmrs for England.
decision, Rivtow Marine Ltd. v. Washington Iron
Works et al., [1974] S.C.R. 1189, a case that has
been frequently cited in the House of Lords.
The plaintiff/appellant had sued for the cost of
repairs to two pintle-type cranes on board a log
barge it had chartered and for loss of the use of
the barge during the repair period. The structural
defects in the cranes were discovered only after a
similar crane had collapsed, killing its operator.
The respondents had been aware that such cranes
were subject to cracking due to negligence in
design, but had not warned the appellant of the
potential danger.
Ritchie J., for the seven Judges in the majority,
held that the lower courts were right in disallowing
the claim for repairs and for such economic loss as
it would in any event have sustained even if proper
warning had been given. He wrote (at page 1207):
Mr. Justice Tysoe's conclusion [in the B.C. Court of Appeal
in the same case] was based in large measure on a series of
American cases, and particularly Trans World Airlines Inc. v.
Curtiss-Wright Corp. ((1955), 148 N.Y.S. 2d 284), where it is
pointed out that the liability for the cost of repairing damage to
the defective article itself and for the economic loss flowing
directly from the negligence, is akin to liability under the terms
of an express or implied warranty of fitness and as it is
contractual in origin cannot be enforced against the manufac
turer by a stranger to the contract. It was, I think, on this basis
that the learned trial judge disallowed the appellant's claim for
repairs and for such economic loss as it would, in any event,
have sustained even if the proper warning had been given. I
agree with this conclusion for the same reasons; but while this
finding excludes recovery for damage to the article and eco
nomic loss directly flowing from Washington's negligence and
faulty design, it does not exclude the additional damage occa
sioned by breach of the duty to warn of the danger.
However, because in Mr. Justice Ritchie's view the
failure to warn was an independent tort, he
believed the Trial Judge was right in allowing and
the Court of Appeal wrong in disallowing, eco
nomic loss resulting from the inactivity of the
barge for the period after the respondents became
seized with the defects.
To support this conclusion Ritchie J. interpreted
Cattle in the light of Donoghue v. Stevenson and
relied heavily on Hedley Byrne (at
pages 1213-1215):
In the present case there is no suggestion that liability should
be based on negligent misrepresentation and to this extent the
Hedley Byrne case is of no relevance. I refer to it for the sole
purpose of indicating the view of the House of Lords that where
liability is based on negligence the recovery is not limited to
physical damage but extends also to economic loss. The case
was recently distinguished in this Court in J. Nunes Diamonds
Ltd. v. Dominion Electric Protection Co. ([1972] S.C.R. 769),
where Pigeon J., speaking for the majority of the Court, said at
p. 777:
Furthermore, the basis of tort liability considered in
Hedley Byrne is inapplicable to any case where the relation
ship between the parties is governed by a contract, unless the
negligence relied on can properly be considered as "an
independent tort" unconnected with the performance of that
contract ... This is specially important in the present case on
account of the provisions of the contract with respect to the
nature of the obligations assumed and the practical exclusion
of responsibility for failure to perform them.
In the present case, however, I am of opinion that the failure
to warn was "an independent tort" unconnected with the
performance of any contract either express or implied.
In the course of the exhaustive argument which he presented
on behalf of the appellant, Mr. Locke referred to a number of
recent decisions in the Court of Appeal of England to illustrate
the development of the thinking in that Court on the question
of recovery for pure economic loss in an action for negligence
where no physical damage has been sustained by the plaintiff.
In one such case, SCM (United Kingdom) Ltd. v. W. J.
Whittal & Son Ltd. ([1970] 3 All E.R. 245), the Court held
that economic loss flowing directly from physical harm was
recoverable but Lord Denning indicated that he would deny
recovery for other economic loss except in exceptional circum
stances. His reasoning appears to rest on the basis that the
damage was too remote although he observed, in the courts of
his judgment:
I must not be taken, however, as saying that economic loss
is always too remote.
A further lengthy discussion of the same subject is contained in
the reasons for judgment of the same learned judge in Spartan
Steel & Alloys Ltd. v. Martin & Co. (Contractors) Ltd.
([1972] 3 W.L.R. 502), where he appears to treat the question
of remoteness of damage as one to be determined "as a matter
of policy" and after referring to the cases of Cattle v. Stockton
Waterworks Co. and Societe Anonyme de Remorquage a
Helice v. Bennetts, he said:
On the other hand, in the cases where economic loss by
itself has been held to be recoverable, it is plain that there
was a duty to the plaintiff and the loss was not too remote.
In the case of Ministry of Housing and Local Government v.
Sharp ([19701 2 Q.B. 223), at p. 278, Salmon L.J. appears to
me to have dealt with the question both accurately and suc
cinctly when he said:
So far, however, as the law of negligence relating to civil
actions is concerned, the existence of a duty to take reason
able care no longer depends on whether it is physical injury
or financial loss which can reasonably be foreseen as a result
of a failure to take such care.
I am conscious of the fact that I have not referred to all
relevant authorities relating to recovery for economic loss under
such circumstances, but I am satisfied that in the present case
there was a proximity of relationship giving rise to a duty to
warn and that the damages awarded by the learned trial judge
were recoverable as compensation for the direct and demonstr
ably foreseeable result of the breach ....
The two Judges dissenting in part would have
included in the allowable loss the cost of repair of
the cranes on the ground that threatened physical
harm should be treated the same as actual physical
harm. Laskin J. (as he then was) wrote (at pages
1218-1219 S.C.R.):
... the doctrine of Hedley Byrne & Co. Ltd. v. Heller &
Partners Ltd., which has been considered in this Court and had
been applied in other Courts in Canada, shows that economic
or pecuniary loss is not outside the scope of liability for
negligence.
The present case is not of the Hedley Byrne type, as the
reasons of my brother Ritchie show, but recovery for economic
loss alone is none the less supported under negligence doctrine.
It seems to me that the rationale of manufacturers' liability for
negligence should equally support such recovery in the case
where, as here, there is a threat of physical harm and the
plaintiff is in the class of those who are foreseeably so
threatened ....
Support for such recovery in the present case will not lead to
"liability in an indeterminate amount for an indeterminate time
to an indeterminate class", to borrow an often-quoted state
ment of the late Judge Cardozo in Ultramares Corp. v. Touche,
at p. 179. The pragmatic considerations which underlay Cattle
v. Stockton Waterworks Co. will not be eroded by the imposi
tion of liability upon Washington as a negligent designer and
manufacturer .... Liability here will not mean that it must
also be imposed in the case of any negligent conduct where
there is foreseeable economic loss; a typical instance would be
claims by employees for lost wages where their employer's
factory has been damaged and is shut down by reason of
another's negligence. The present case is concerned with direct
economic loss by a person whose use of the defendant Washing-
ton's product was a contemplated one, and not with indirect
economic loss by third parties, for example, persons whose logs
could not be loaded on the appellant's barge because of the
withdrawal of the defective crane from service to undergo
repairs. It is concerned (and here I repeat myself) with econom-
is loss resulting directly from avoidance of threatened physical
harm to property of the appellant if not also personal injury to
persons in its employ.
Despite the wider recovery he would have
allowed, Laskin J. is much closer to the exclusion-
ary rule than the majority because of his retention
of the physical harm concept. For the majority, it
seems that any economic loss which occurs apart
from a relationship between the plaintiff and the
tortfeasor is recoverable if there is a sufficient
"proximity of relationship" between the two par
ties. In fact, the principle adopted by the majority
is the corollary to that adopted by the majority in
Nunes Diamonds (J.) Ltd. v. Dominion Electric
Protection Co., [1972] S.C.R. 769. Ritchie J.
quotes Pigeon J. in that case (at page 777) to the
effect that "the basis of tort liability considered in
Hedley Byrne is inapplicable to any case where the
relationship between the parties is governed by a
contract". It may well be simply an accident of
timing that Rivtow Marine followed soon after
Hedley Byrne and before the House of Lords'
negative reaction set in the 1980's, but it remains
the principal Canadian authority, although subse
quent English cases have been remarked upon in
passing several times by the Supreme Court, most
notably in Kamloops (City of) v. Nielsen et al.,
[1984] 2 S.C.R. 2.
The issue in Kamloops was whether a munici
pality can be held liable for negligence in failing to
prevent the construction of a house with defective
foundations by a purchaser who took it without
notice either of the state of the foundations or of
the inadequacy of the municipal surveillance.
Wilson J. for the majority extensively surveyed
the cases on recovery for pure economic loss, since
the municipality argued that the economic loss in
the case was analogous to the cost of repairs to the
crane which was expressly disallowed by the
majority in Rivtow Marine. Wilson J. acknowl
edged (at page 33) that "the majority judgment of
this Court in Rivtow stands until such time as it
may be reconsidered by a full panel of the Court",
but she added that (at page 34):
... I tend to think that the problem of concurrent liability in
contract and tort played a major role in the restrictive approach
taken by the majority in Rivtow and that, as in the case of
Hedley Byrne, we will have to await the outcome of a develop
ing jurisprudence around that decision also .
However, she distinguished Rivtow Marine on
at least two grounds: (1) Rivtow was a lawsuit
between private litigants as compared with a claim
against a public authority for breach of a private-
law duty of care arising under a statute; (2) "there
are no contractual overtones to this case as there
were in Rivtow" (at page 34), where there was
"some concern that the tort door should not be
opened so far as to permit a recovery in tort which
would not have been available in contract" (at
page 34). Neither the result nor the reasons are
therefore directly relevant to the case at bar, since
recovery was ultimately allowed on a statutory
basis. Nevertheless, it seems to me that both the
thrust and the tone of what the Court did militate
against an absolute exclusionary rule. The summa
tion on the issue by Wilson J. points this way (at
page 35):
I do not believe that to permit recovery in this case is to
expose public authorities to the indeterminate liability referred
to in Ultramares. In order to obtain recovery for economic loss
the statute has to create a private law duty to the plaintiff
alongside the public law duty. The plaintiff has to belong to the
limited class of owners or occupiers of the property at the time
the damage manifests itself. Loss caused as a result of policy
decisions made by the public authority in the bona fide exercise
of discretion will not be compensable. Loss caused in the
implementation of policy decisions will not be compensable if
the operational decision includes a policy element. Loss caused
in the implementation of policy decisions, i.e. operational negli
gence will be compensable. Loss will also be compensable if the
implementation involves policy considerations and the discre
tion exercised by the public authority is not exercised in good
faith. Finally, and perhaps this merits some emphasis, economic
loss will only be recoverable if as a matter of statutory interpre
tation it is a type of loss the statute intended to guard against.
It seems to me that recovery for economic loss on the
foregoing basis accomplishes a number of worthy objectives. It
avoids undue interference by the courts in the affairs of public
authorities. It gives a remedy where the legislature has implied-
ly sanctioned it and justice clearly requires it. It imposes
enough of a burden on public authorities to act as a check on
the arbitrary and negligent discharge of statutory duties. For
these reasons I would permit recovery of the economic loss in
this case.
What is most striking, perhaps, is the majority's
refusal to be stampeded by any floodgates argu
ment based upon Cardozo C.J.'s statement in
Ultramares.
The appellants in the case at bar contended that
the decision of Wilson J. in Kamloops should be
read in the light of her alleged affirmation of the
exclusionary rule as a member of the Ontario
Court of Appeal in Attorney-General for Ontario
v. Fatehi et al. (1981), 34 O.R. (2d) 129 (C.A.),
but in my view that contention breaks down on an
analysis of the Fatehi decision in the Ontario
Court of Appeal. In that case, the defendant
admitted negligence in the operation of a motor
vehicle, but denied liability for the Ontario
Crown's costs in clearing the wrecked vehicles,
spilled gasoline, broken glass, and general debris
from a highway. Brooke J.A. (dissenting) would
have upheld the Trial Judge's decision that the
Crown was a property-owner whose property had
suffered damage.
It is perhaps fair to say that both Wilson and
Thorson JJ.A. in the majority inclined to the
exclusionary rule in their dicta. Indeed, Thorson
J.A. admitted (at page 146):
If it had been necessary to do so in this case on the
theoretical assumption that the only ground for appeal argued
by counsel for the appellant was that the Crown's loss was a
purely economic one, I would have been disposed to allow the
appeal on that ground.
Wilson J.A. (as she then was) was, however,
ultimately unwilling to rest her judgment on the
exclusionary rule (at page 142):
However, even if I am right that this is an action for the
recovery of pure economic loss I cannot say on the existing
state of the law that the learned trial Judge was clearly wrong
in permitting recovery. I prefer therefore to base my judgment
on the appellant's second ground of appeal.
On appeal, the Supreme Court of Canada
unanimously held that the case was not one of
economic loss at all but of direct damage to the
property of the plaintiff occasioned by the negli
gence of the defendant. The Supreme Court inter
preted the Court of Appeal majority below as
having suspended judgment on pure economic loss
(supra, at page 544):
The law in Canada remains, as was said in the majority below,
somewhat uncertain by reason of the decision of this Court in
Rivtow Marine, supra.
The Supreme Court's own view was that the law
was open, and that it should remain so for the
moment (at page 545):
Nonetheless it must be acknowledged that Rivtow has been
variously applied or rejected by the courts of this country, some
of whom find in the majority judgment recognition of economic
loss and some of whom have found the opposite. It is not
possible to say whether the law of Canada, as reflected in the
authorities to date, contemplates recovery for a pure economic
loss in the sense of Junior Books, supra, in the House of Lords.
In this proceeding it is unnecessary, in my view, to settle this
issue because ... this is not a case of economic loss but of direct
damage to property of the plaintiff occasioned by the negli
gence of the respondent.
Although the issue was specifically left open by
the Supreme Court of Canada in Fatehi as in
Kamloops, the straws in the wind, if I may call
them that, seem to incline against the exclusionary
rule. Thus in Agnew-Surpass Shoe Stores Ltd. v.
Cummer-Yonge Investments Ltd., [1976]
2 S.C.R. 221, Pigeon J., writing for four Judges,
said of the Rivtow decision, in which he had been
part of the majority, (at page 252):
It is now settled by the judgment of this Court in Rivtow
Marine Ltd. v. Washington Iron Works that recovery for
economic loss caused by negligence is allowable without any
recovery for property damage.
He therefore held in Agnew-Surpass that an
exculpatory clause for a lessee should be narrowly
interpreted so as to leave the lessee liable for a loss
of rental income on the part of the owner-landlord
of a shopping centre where a fire had been caused
through his negligence.
Similarly, in Haig v. Bamford et al., [1977] 1
S.C.R. 466, a case where the Supreme Court
allowed recovery against accountants who had
failed to use reasonable care in the preparation of
accounts, Dickson J. (as he then was) wrote for six
of the nine Judges (at page 483) with no words of
qualification, "Recovery for economic loss caused
by negligence has been allowed in Rivtow Marine
Ltd. v. Washington Iron Works".
Moreover, it was argued with some justification
by the respondent on the present appeal that
Madam Justice Wilson's emphasis in Kamloops in
a series of rhetorical questions summarizing the
reassessment of the exclusionary rule implied her
own favourable answers to the questions (at
pages 28-29):
It took the decision of the House of Lords in Hedley Byrne &
Co. Ltd. v. Heller & Partners Ltd., supra, to spark a review
and reassessment of the economic loss rule by legal scholars
and judges, and this review has been going on now for almost
two decades. How, it is asked, can one justify to injured
plaintiffs the difference in treatment the law accords to physi
cal and to economic loss caused by a defendant's negligent
acts? In one you are compensated by the wrongdoer: in the
other you have to bear the loss yourself. Does it make sense to
permit the recovery of economic loss for negligent words but
not for negligent acts? What is the significant difference
between them? Why, if economic loss is reasonably foreseeable
as a consequence of negligent acts, should it not be as recover
able as reasonably foreseeable physical injury to persons or to
property? And should Chief Judge Cardozo's fear of indetermi
nate liability to an indeterminate class preclude recovery by a
very specific plaintiff in a very specific amount? Can a policy
consideration which leads to a manifest injustice in certain
types of cases be a good policy consideration? Is there some
rationale whereby injustice in specific cases can be avoided and
Chief Judge Cardozo's fear guarded against at the same time?
Two other recent Supreme Court of Canada
decisions are relevant. In B.D.C. Ltd. v. Hofstrand
Farms Ltd., [1986] 1 S.C.R. 228, where a courier
was unaware that an envelope contained a Crown
grant that had to be registered within a stipulated
time, it was held by the Court that there was no
duty of care as required by the first Anns proposi
tion. Nevertheless, Estey J. widely surveyed the
law of negligence and pure economic loss, taking
the same view as Pigeon J. in Agnew-Surpass of
Rivtow Marine (at pages 239-240):
In Rivtow Marine Ltd. v. Washington Iron Works, [1974]
S.C.R. 1189, this Court divided on some aspects of the issue of
negligently caused economic loss, but both the majority and the
dissenting judgments recognized that, in principle, a defendant
could be held liable in tort for economic losses arising wholly in
the absence of associated physical injury or damage. Rivtow
concerned the liability of the manufacturer of a defectively
made crane to the crane's ultimate consumer, for the cost of the
repairs and for profits lost while the crane was out of service.
The case therefore raised issues of products liability and bears
little resemblance to Hedley Byrne, supra, and the cases follow
ing it. Consistently with the cases cited supra, however, both
Ritchie J. for the majority and Laskin J., as he then was, in
dissent referred to the need to find sufficient proximity between
the parties to the action.
Estey J. stressed the necessity of a "proximity"
test throughout, ostensibly in relation to the first
Anns principle, but often in contexts (e.g. Junior
Books) where it could reasonably be applied to the
second Anns proposition.
The other Supreme Court case is Central Trust
Co. v. Rafuse, [1986] 2 S.C.R. 147, where the
principal issue was whether a solicitor could be
liable to a client in tort as well as in contract. Le
Dain J. delivered the reasons for decision of the
Court and on the relevant point said (at page 206):
3. A concurrent or alternative liability in tort will not be
admitted if its effect would be to permit the plaintiff to
circumvent or escape a contractual exclusion or limitation of
liability for the act or omission that would constitute the tort.
Subject to this qualification, where concurrent liability in tort
and contract exists the plaintiff has the right to assert the cause
of action that appears to be most advantageous to him in
respect of any particular legal consequence.
Where there is no question of a contractual exclu
sion, it was thus held that the principle of Hedley
Byrne should be applied.
These two cases add nothing directly with
respect to the exclusionary rule, but it seems to me
that both point in the direction of limiting it.
B.D.C. [at page 239] approves a broad statement
that, on the basis of Rivtow Marine, "a defendant
could be held liable in tort for economic losses
arising wholly in the absence of associated physical
injury or damage". Central Trust [at page 206]
would support the exclusionary rule only where
otherwise the plaintiff could "circumvent or escape
a contractual exclusion or limitation of liability".
There was one case in which this Court con
sidered the issue of recovery for pure economic
loss: Baird v. The Queen in right of Canada,
[1984] 2 F.C. 160 (C.A.). In that case, the Trial
Judge [(1982), 135 D.L.R. (3d) 371] had struck
out the statement of claim as disclosing no cause
of action on the ground that a claim for compensa
tion for economic loss was not within the scope of
Crown liability when the statutory duties in issue
were imposed upon the Minister of Finance and
the Superintendent of Insurance. In reversing, Mr.
Justice Le Dain said for the majority of the Court
(at page 183):
The next question is whether, if there were a duty of care
owed by the Minister of Finance or the Superintendent of
Insurance to the appellants and a breach of that duty, there
could in principle be recovery for purely economic loss. Counsel
for the Crown contended that the kinds of cases in which there
could be recovery for economic loss that is not consequential
upon personal injury or property damage were limited to those
represented by Hedley Byrne & Co. Ltd. v. Heller & Partners
Ltd., [1964] A.C. 465 (H.L.) and Rivtow Marine, supra:
negligent misrepresentation, and negligent failure to warn of a
dangerous defect in a product. There is in my opinion nothing
in subsequent judicial commentary on this question which
suggests that recovery for purely economic loss is to be limited
in principle to these categories of cases. In Agnew-Surpass
Shoe Stores Ltd. v. Cummer-Yonge Investments Ltd., [1976]
2 S.C.R. 221 at page 252 there was the following general
reference to the significance of Rivtow Marine: "It is now
settled by the judgment of this Court in Rivtow Marine Ltd. v.
Washington Iron Works et al. ([1974] S.C.R. 1189) that
recovery for economic loss caused by negligence is allowable
without any recovery for property damage." It would appear
that whether such recovery will be permitted in a particular
case of negligence will depend on the application of general
principles or considerations not confined to certain categories or
types of cases. These principles and considerations are very
fully examined in Caltex Oil, supra, which was itself an
example of recovery for purely economic loss in a case which
did not fall within the Hedley Byrne and Rivtow Marine
categories. Whether the question is to be approached from the
point of view of duty of care or remoteness of damage or
generally as a policy question it is not plain and obvious to me
at this stage that the possibility of such recovery in the present
case should be excluded as a matter of principle.
Again, this is something less than a decisive au
thority, but it is significant that the Court looked
on the rule as broader than would be encompassed
in the categories of cases represented by Hedley
Byrne and Rivtow Marine, and believed that
"whether such recovery will be permitted in a
particular case of negligence will depend on the
application of general principles or considerations
not confined to certain categories or types of
cases," such as were set out in Caltex.
There are also three cases in the Trial Division,
Gypsum Carrier Inc. v. The Queen, [1978] 1 F.C.
147; Bethlehem Steel Corporation v. St. Lawrence
Seaway Authority, [1978] 1 F.C. 464; and
Interocean Shipping Company v. The Ship Atlan-
tic Splendour, [1984] 1 F.C. 931. The Gypsum
Carrier case not only involved a ship collision with
the same bridge as in the case at bar but is on all
fours with it save that there seems to have been
scant evidence as to foreseeability and no argu
ment made as to the proximity of railway prop
erty. Having found that the railway had neither
easements nor any lesser proprietary interests in
the bridge, Collier J. stated (at page 158):
I am satisfied that, in this case, the absence of physical
damage to any property of the railway companies does not, by
itself, preclude recovery for the additional expense the railway
companies incurred (the economic loss).
Nevertheless, he found that the action failed on
the first Anns principle, viz., that on the evidence
no duty of reasonable care had been established.
In Bethlehem Steel, a ship had collided with and
destroyed a bridge over the Welland Canal. One
claim was for the loss of profits of ships held up by
the obstruction in the Canal, a second for the extra
cost of shipping cargo from Toronto rather than
through the Canal. Addy J. disallowed recovery,
holding that the relationship between the claim
ants and the damaged object had been much closer
in the Gypsum Carrier case, where (at page 470)
"the damaged object was the very thing which was
used by the claimants and they at least had certain
contractual rights covering it." In the case at bar,
he distinguished his previous decision in Beth-
lehem Steel as follows (at page 26 C.C.L.T.):
In that decision, I did indeed approve and apply the floodgates
rule and made no mention of alternatives. However, an exami
nation of the facts of that case indicates quite clearly that no
circumstances whatsoever were present which might have been
capable of prevailing over the very practical objections which
constitute the raison d'être of that exclusionary rule.
In Interocean Shipping, where the Atlantic
Splendour overstayed at a dock because of
mechanical difficulties delaying four other ships
scheduled to take on iron ore at the same dock, on
a stated case Dube J. stated the law as follows (at
pages 936-937):
My assessment of the present state of the developing juris
prudence on this vexed question of pure economic loss is that
there need not be physical injury for the plaintiff to recover,
provided: firstly, there was a duty owing by the defendant to
the plaintiff; secondly, there was a breach of that duty; thirdly,
the economic losses flowed directly from the defendant's negli
gence; and fourthly, the consequences were reasonably
foreseeable.
He went on to distinguish the Gypsum Carrier
case on the facts (at page 938):
Those in charge of the vessel in the Gypsum case could not,
of course, have foreseen the rerouting of trains as they were
heading for the railway bridge. Similarly, the navigators in the
Bethlehem Steel case did not know they were about to disrupt
ship schedules on the canal. But those in charge of the M/V
Atlantic Splendour purposely kept the vessel moored at the
dock, when they could have had her towed away immediately.
They could have prevented the economic damage to the other
vessels, but for their own reasons chose not to do so. They
knew, or ought to have known, that they were monopolizing the
only available berth. They saw, or ought to have seen, the other
vessels sitting idle in the water. It is not beyond the ken of
reasonable seamen to foresee that vessels in waiting suffer
economic losses. The procrastination of the defendant, admitted
or to be proven at trial, was the direct, foreseeable cause of the
economic losses suffered by the plaintiffs.
Provincial appeal courts in three provinces have
denied the exclusionary rule. The most forthright
statement is that of Lambert J.A. for the British
Columbia Court of Appeal in Nicholls v. Town
ship of Richmond et al. (1983), 145 D.L.R. (3d)
362, at page 367, 9 on a motion to strike out a
pleading in a wrongful dismissal case based on
negligently inducing a breach of contract:
So the question in this case becomes: Is there a legal policy
that denies recovery, as a matter of principle, where, in a
relationship of proximity that may exist between officers and
employees of a corporation, an act, omission or misstatement
occurs, and the perpetrator should reasonably have foreseen
that it would result directly in economic loss to a fellow
employee, as, for example, by dismissal from employment? I
am not persuaded that there is or should be such a general legal
policy. In particular cases recovery may be denied as a matter
of policy, but the policy would be a narrower one, applicable on
the basis of facts that are not as yet revealed in this case. I
reach no conclusion now as to the existence or scope of such a
narrower policy.
In my opinion, such cases as Cattle v. Stockton Waterworks
Co. (1875), L.R. 10 Q.B. 453, and Weller & Co. v. Foot &
Mouth Disease Research Institute, [1965] 3 All E.R. 560,
should be seen as specific examples of a denial of recovery on
the basis of absence of proximity, or remoteness of damage, or
both, and not as establishing a principle that damages can
never be recovered for economic loss if the loss arises from the
breach of a contractual relationship between one victim who
suffers economic loss and another victim who suffers physical
injury. The answer to such problems lies not in a uniform
denial of recovery but in an application of the customary and
9 In the disapproving view of Dean Peter J. Burns, "Recent
Developments in Negligence Law", Negligence Law in the
1990's, (Vancouver: The Continuing Legal Society of British
Columbia, (1985), at p. 1.1.10, "the combined effect of Nielson
and Nicholls . . . is the creation of a vastly expanded area and
range of potential civil liability that must ultimately increase
the costs of public and private activities and in many cases even
deter desirable undertakings in the commercial and public
sectors".
sometimes difficult questions relating to proximity, foreseeabili-
ty, causation and remoteness.
Suppose an airline has a policy of discharging pilots who
suffer from a medical disability and requires its pilots to
undergo a medical examination each year by a doctor, selected
by the airline, who knows the purpose of the examination.
Suppose the doctor carelessly and incorrectly diagnoses a disa
bility and the pilot is discharged. Would the pilot, as a matter
of legal policy, be denied a cause of action against the doctor? I
do not think so. Yet the loss suffered by the pilot would be
economic loss arising from the doctor's negligent interference
with the pilot's contractual relations with the airline. I leave
unanswered the question of what difference it would make, if
any, if the doctor was a salaried employee of the airline.
In Maughan and Maughan v. International
Harvester Company of Canada Limited (1980),
38 N.S.R. (2d) 101 (C.A.), although denying an
action against a manufacturer for a breach of
warranty on defective goods to a user who bought
from a dealer without an express warranty, the
Nova Scotia Court of Appeal was prepared to find
the manufacturer liable to the user for economic
loss caused by negligence. MacKeigan C.J.N.S.,
for the Court, interpreted Rivtow Marine in the
light of the comments by Pigeon J. in Agnew-Sur
pass and Dickson J. [as he then was] in Haig, and
said (at page 109):
I need not strain ... to find factual similarity with Rivtow.
Mr. Justice Ritchie rejected the idea of any special rule
restricting recovery of economic loss in negligence cases.
In Yumerovski et al. v. Dani (1977), 18 O.R.
(2d) 704 (Co. Ct.), affd (1979), 120 D.L.R. (3d)
768 (Ont. C.A.), where the negligent driving of a
travel agent taking members of a family to their
charter flight caused the death of one of the
passengers, leading the other members of the
deceased's family to forgo the trip, they sued for
the cost of the tickets, and the Trial Judge allowed
recovery, following Caltex. On appeal, MacKin-
non A.C.J.O. concisely stated for the Ontario
Court of Appeal (at page 768):
Because of the special relationship between the parties which
was established by the defendant's undertaking, as part of the
inducement to the plaintiffs to purchase the airline tickets from
him, to drive one or more of the members of this limited and
closely knit family group to the airport, and for the reasons
given by the trial Judge, the appeal is dismissed with costs.
There are a number of other cases in which
lower courts have allowed recovery for economic
loss in the absence of property damage: University
of Regina v. Pettick et al. (1986), 51 Sask. R. 270
(Q.B.); Dominion Tape of Canada Ltd. v. L. R.
McDonald & Sons Ltd. et al., [1971] 3 O.R. 627
(Co. Ct.); Smith et al. v. Melancon, [1976] 4
W.W.R. 9 (B.C.S.C.); MacMillan Bloedel Ltd. v.
Foundation Company of Canada Ltd. (1977), 75
D.L.R. (3d) 294 (B.C.S.C.); Trappa Holdings
Ltd. v. District of Surrey et al. (1978), 95 D.L.R.
(3d) 107 (B.C.S.C.); Gold v. The DeHavilland
Aircraft of Can. Ltd., [1983] 6 W.W.R. 229
(B.C.S.C.).
IV
In my view, this survey of the law leads to the
apparent conclusion that in Canada there is no
absolute rule preventing recovery for pure econom
ic loss even where there is no physical damage to
the plaintiff's property. This it seems to me, is the
only possible conclusion to be drawn from Rivtow
Marine, Agnew-Surpass, Haig and Baird.w
What the courts insist upon for liability, again
and again from Hedley Byrne on, is that there
must be a special relationship or sufficient prox
imity between the plaintiff and the defendant:
"sufficient proximity" (Stephen J. in Caltex and
Estey J. in B.D.C.); "proximity" (Lord Roskill in
Junior Books); "loss .. . not too remote" (Lord
Denning, M.R., in Spartan Steel & Alloys Ltd. v.
Martin & Co. (Contractors) Ltd., [1973] Q.B. 27
(C.A.) at page 37, as cited by Ritchie J. in Rivtow
10 This would also appear to be the situation under Quebec's
Civil Code. Daniel Jutras, "Civil Law and Pure Economic Loss:
What Are We Missing?" (1987), 12 Can. Bus. L.J. 295, at p.
309 writes that "there is some evidence that neither Quebec nor
France has a de facto rule precluding the recovery of pure
economic loss." Cf. also the critique of privity of contract, from
a comparative law point of view, in B. S. Markesinis, "An
Expanding Tort Law—The Price of a Rigid Contract Law"
(1987), 103 L.Q. Rev. 354.
Marine." I think it is thus latent in the cases that
a principle of sufficient proximity is required, in
addition to the general principle of reasonable
foresight, for liability to arise in the case of pure
economic loss.
A possible conceptual difficulty with a sufficient
proximity principle is that it may lead to confusion
between Lord Wilberforce's two propositions in
Anns, as it does, arguably, in B.D.C. The first
proposition in Anns [at page 751] flows directly
from Donoghue v. Stevenson: "whether, as be
tween the alleged wrongdoer and the person who
suffered damage there is a sufficient relationship
of proximity or neighbourhood".
However, Lord Wilberforce's second proposi
tion, as I see it, does not have to be entirely
separate from his first. "[w]hether there are any
considerations which ought to negative, or to
reduce or limit the scope of the duty or the class of
person to whom it is owed or the damages to which
a breach of it may give rise" [at page 752] is
perhaps not so much a separate question as a
reflection on and a deepening of, the answer to the
II Lord Denning uses a similar phrase "too remote to be
recovered as damages" in S.C.M. (United Kingdom) Ltd. v. W.
J. Whittall and Son Ltd., [1971] 1 Q.B. 337 (C.A.) at pp.
344-345. He then (at p. 346) offers this summation:
Seeing these exceptional cases you may well ask: How are
we to say when economic loss is too remote or not? Where is
the line to be drawn? Lawyers are continually asking that
question. But the judges are never defeated by it. We may
not be able to draw the line with precision, but we can always
say on which side of it any particular case falls. The same
question might be asked in the case of the escaping borstal
boys. If their house masters are negligent, and they escape
and do damage, the Home Office are liable to persons in the
neighbourhood, but not to those far away. Where, again, is
the line to be drawn? Only where "in the particular case the
good sense of the judge decides." That is how Lord Wright
put it in the case of nervous shock in Bourhill v. Young
[1943] A.C. 93, 110: and I do not think we can get any
nearer than that. But, by building up a body of case law, we
shall give guidance to practitioners sufficient for all the
ordinary cases that arise.
first. It can lead to a possible negation of the first,
but for reasons that may be intrinsic and already
contained in the answer to the first question, even
if it is affirmative—because it is not affirmative
enough, as it were.
Even where the second question appears to be an
entirely separate one, the negative considerations it
raises are really all boiled down to the avoidance
of "indeterminate" liability, that is, to the necessi
ty of tying any liability down to something deter
minate. This second issue, it seems to me, may be
thought of as measured by the degree of the
proximity in the first answer. In other words, while
the first question envisions that the parties be
neighbours, the second necessitates that they be
close neighbours. The first answer may in one
sense be said to respond to both questions, even
though in my view they are best put separately.
In Spartan Steel, supra, at page 36, Lord Den-
ning prefers to express the resolution of liability
for economic loss in terms of a pure policy
decision:
At bottom I think the question of recovering economic loss is
one of policy. Whenever the courts draw a line to mark out the
bounds of duty, they do it as matter of policy so as to limit the
responsibility of the defendant. Whenever the courts set bounds
to the damages recoverable—saying that they are, or are not,
too remote—they do it as matter of policy so as to limit the
liability of the defendant.
My own approach is to look to principle rather
than to policy, and so to think of the judgment
required for liability for pure economic loss, not as
a pure policy decision, but as a perception of
sufficient proximity, that is, in terms of a measur
able determinacy. Mr. Justice Linden, Canadian
Tort Law, 4th ed., at page 393, suggests that the
issue may be resolved by identifying categories of
loss:
... categories of economic loss cases will have to be identified
just as the recurring situations have been isolated in the
remoteness area generally. Specific limiting formulae may be
adopted to meet the unique loss distribution and indeterminate
class problems within each category. The need for compensa
tion, deterrence, education and market deterrence will have to
be assessed in each context, such as products liability, negligent
statements, utilities, public authorities, etc.
Certainly the factual surroundings are critical in
analyzing potential liability.
The best statement I have found of what I
believe is the applicable principle, viz., the prox
imity principle, is by Deane J. of the High Court
of Australia in Sutherland Shire Council v
Heyman (1985), 60 ALR 1, at pages 55-56:
The requirement of proximity is directed to the relationship
between the parties in so far as it is relevant to the allegedly
negligent act or omission of the defendant and the loss or injury
sustained by the plaintiff. It involves the notion of nearness or
closeness and embraces physical proximity (in the sense of
space and time) between the person or property of the plaintiff
and the person or property of the defendant, circumstantial
proximity such as an overriding relationship of employer and
employee or of a professional man and his client and what may
(perhaps loosely) be referred to as causal proximity in the sense
of the closeness or directness of the causal connection or
relationship between the particular act or course of conduct and
the loss or injury sustained. It may reflect an assumption by
one party of a responsibility to take care to avoid or prevent
injury, loss or damage to the person or property of another or
reliance by one party upon such care being taken by the other
in circumstances where the other party knew or ought to have
known of that reliance. Both the identity and the relative
importance of the factors which are determinative of an issue of
proximity are likely to vary in different categories of case. That
does not mean that there is scope for decision by reference to
idiosyncratic notions of justice or morality or that it is a proper
approach to treat the requirement of proximity as a question of
fact to be resolved merely by reference to the relationship
between the plaintiff and the defendant in the particular cir
cumstances. The requirement of a relationship of proximity
serves as a touchstone and control of the categories of case in
which the common law will adjudge that a duty of care is owed.
Given the general circumstances of a case in a new or develop
ing area of the law of negligence, the question what (if any)
combination or combinations of factors will satisfy the require
ment of proximity is a question of law to be resolved by the
processes of legal reasoning, induction and deduction. On the
other hand, the identification of the content of that requirement
in such an area should not be either ostensibly or actually
divorced from notions of what is "fair and reasonable"... .
I would agree that the requisite proximity can
consist of various forms of closeness physical,
circumstantial, causal, assumed—and that "The
requirement of a relationship of proximity serves
as a touchstone and control of the categories of
case in which the common law will adjudge that a
duty of care is owed."
In my observation, courts will always find suffi
cient proximity where there is physical danger to
the plaintiff's property. In fact, I believe that
might be said to have the status of a presumption.
But where there is no physical damage, there is in
my view no presumption but rather neutrality as to
possible conclusions. Still, other factors may give
rise to a conclusion of proximity.
What is always to be avoided is liability in an
indeterminate amount for an indeterminate time to
an indeterminate class. As Michael A. Jones, Note
["Economic Loss A Return to Pragmation"]
(1986), 102 L.Q. Rev. 13 at page 15, has put it,
"The cases in which the courts have allowed recov
ery for economic loss have all involved situations in
which a conceptual control could be placed on the
defendant's potential liability." Otherwise, as was
said in the latest House of Lords trilogy, a fatal
lack of certainty in the law could result. But
certainty by itself, without the guiding vision of
justice, would lead to a blind alley. The law
demands some perception of justice for its life,
even while it requires some channelling of justice
for its survival.
I might add that the recent House of Lords'
cases in particular would strongly suggest that,
where tort liability appears to be a way of getting
around the limitations of contract law, there may
be said to be a presumption against any liability in
tort. That view is, however, expressed in a more
moderate fashion by the Supreme Court in Central
Trust, and in any event is not relevant in the case
at bar.
With this background of principle, I can now
turn to the case at bar.
V
Addy J. rested his conclusion as to liability on
three grounds: (1) the captain of the tugboat was
specifically aware of the CNR as a party likely to
suffer damage from any negligence to the point
that he believed the bridge to belong to the CNR;
(2) the precise nature of the economic loss to the
CNR was actually known to the tortfeasor, since
previous accidents to the bridge had caused pre
cisely the same result; (3) the property of the
CNR (the tracks on both sides of the Fraser
River) is not only in close proximity to the bridge
but this riverside property cannot be properly
enjoyed without the essential link of the bridge,
which is an integral part of its railway system.
Linked with the third ground is the CNR's role in
supplying materials and inspection and consulting
services for the bridge, and the CNR's preponder
ant usage of the bridge, recognized even in the
periodic negotiations for routine maintenance clos-
ings. The Trial Judge also concluded that the
economic loss claimed was not disproportionate to
the physical damage to the bridge.
To my mind the actual knowledge of the appel
lants found by the Trial Judge was not necessary
for liability; all that was required in this regard
was reasonable foreseeability. As to the principle
of sufficient proximity, I find it realized by the
third ground in particular. In effect, the Trial
Judge found that the CNR was so closely
assimilated to the position of PWC that it was very
much within the reasonable ambit of risk of the
appellants at the time of the accident. That, it
seems to me, is sufficient proximity: in Deane J.'s
language, it is both physical and circumstantial
closeness.
In the light of the law as I understand it, I can
see no error in the learned Trial Judge's conclu
sion. The situation is a unique one, unique even to
the CNR among the three railways. I believe Addy
J. has correctly interpreted and applied the law as
it stands in Canada.
I would therefore dismiss the appeal with costs.
HEALD J.A.: I concur.
You are being directed to the most recent version of the statute which may not be the version considered at the time of the judgment.